Discussion Papers 2001. 
Role of the Regions in the Enlarging European Union 194-213. p.
Role of the Regions in the Enlarging European Union 
Edited by Zoltan Gal, Pecs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001 
RETHINKING REGIONAL 
GOVERNANCE AND PLANNING 
Henk Voogd 
Introduction 
Regional planning has not been the most popular branch of planning  (Wannop, 
1995). Several authors  (Classon,  1974;  Martins,  1986) have argued that the 
acceptance and success of regional planning strongly depend on the adminis-
trative strength of the authority that is responsible for this task. If this authority 
is weak or absent, regional planning was often seen by local authorities as an 
obscure ritual or administrative luxury  (Self,  1980). 
In the past regional planning was often primarily seen as a governmental ac-
tivity aimed at the production and review of some kind of a 'regional plan'. 
However, planning theory has already taught us for many years that planning 
involves more than just that  (Healey,  1997). Modern regional planning is much 
more than the application of regional development theories, such as developed 
in traditional economics  (Hilhorst,  1967, 1971). It is not only an intellectual 
process, but also a social, political as well as organisational process. Control of 
urban sprawl and mobility is impossible without regional co-ordination involv-
ing multiple local authorities and relevant stakeholders. Environmental pollu-
tion doesn't respect local boundaries either and likewise other public affairs can 
often be best dealt with on a regional level such as, for instance, waste and wa-
ter management. Internationalisation and globalisation are tendencies that also 
support a stronger regional representation in order to remain visible in the 
European and worldwide competition. These and other phenomenon have im-
plications and certainly encourage a regional approach, which includes not only 
government but non-governmental actors too. 
John Glasson (1974) has made many years ago a valuable conceptual dis-
tinction between inter-regional planning and intra-regional planning.  Inter-re-
gional planning 
is planning between regions. Its main aim is derived from so-
cial welfare since it seeks to change the economic inequality of regions. It is 
also denoted as 'regional development', which has received a lot of attention in 
literature  (Cappelin—Batey,  1993;  Molle—Cappelin,  1988;  Hilpert,  1991;  Hil- 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning 
195 
horst,  1967, 1971). However, most of these studies are not dealing with plan-
ning itself, but with empirical characteristics of regional-economic develop-
ment and/or ex post evaluation of economic policy measures.  Intra-regional 
planning is planning within a region, but at a higher level than local authorities. 
The primary aim of intra-regional planning is to achieve a satisfactory relation-
ship between people, jobs, and the environment within a region. Inter-regional 
planning is often seen as a task of national authorities or international commu-
nities, such as the European Union  (Cappelin,  1993). Intra-regional planning is 
linked with a regional authority, be it  a  formal regional government or a coali-
tion of local governments and/or other stakeholders. 
The modern view of planning coincides with the proliferation of the word 
' governance'  in recent years. Although this term has slightly different mean-
ings in different disciplines, such as management science and political science, 
and also in USA and Europe  (Lefevre,  1998), the commonality can be best de-
scribed as the management of the common affairs of political communities by 
active collaboration of various interests. The most important characteristic of 
governance is that it involves more than government. It explicitly includes other 
stakeholders who together attempt to determine the progress of developments in 
a region. 
This purpose of this paper is to discuss some implications of regional gov-
ernance for regional planning. It is started with a systems view at the relation 
between governance and government. In addition the relationship between gov-
ernance and network theory is outlined. Next the obvious association between 
collaborative planning and governance will be discussed. Although some 
authors defend governance without government  (Rhodes,  1996), it will be ex-
plained that so-called 'social dilemmas' exist that cannot be solved without a 
superimposed authority, or government. It is illustrated by Dutch regional 
transportation practice that regional governance may need an external stimulus 
to survive. It will be concluded, that modern regional governance may imply a 
shift from traditional comprehensive governmental planning to more 'tailor-
made' planning approaches, such as the formulation of agreement packages 
(covenants) between stakeholders. 
From government to governance: a periodic swing? 
There is little question that societies are becoming increasingly complex. Some 
planners therefore argue that complexity should be a touchstone for the plan-
ning approach to be followed  (De Roo,  1999). Systems theory  (Linstone,  1996) 
and also history  (Kuhn,  1969;  Kennedy,  1989) teach us that the evolution of 
complex systems generally appears to proceed by periodic swings between 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
196 
H. Voogd 
opposite system characteristics. For example, a hierarchical system grows until 
it can no longer be effectively managed or controlled centrally. The next stage 
is that it disintegrates into smaller units with considerable autonomy. Ulti-
mately this disintegration goes too far and the system is no longer effective. 
Then a reunification process starts, which brings the system usually at a higher 
level of complexity than existed previously; and so on. 
Modis  (1994) describes this evolutionary pattern of alternating system states 
as phases of growth and stagnation, or 'order' and 'disorder'. Order means 
growth through development of system components in an internally compatible 
way with overall stability, which implies that the technology or organisation is 
successful. This is followed by a phase of disorder: growth stagnates, resulting 
in instability. In this phase, new technological and organisational options are 
explored. This is followed by a stage where new organisational and technologi-
cal concepts provide a new order and a stable growth; and so on. 
Linstone  and  Mitroff  (1994) also observed that complex system evolution 
generally appears to proceed by periodic swings between centralization and 
decentralization. They depict systems growth as alternating processes of growth 
and stagnation, of order and chaos. They illustrate that there is much empirical 
evidence that societal systems behave in this way. Changing information, com-
munication and transportation technologies have in the past lead to profound 
changes in organisations, their geographical behaviour and also their manage-
ment (Kennedy,  1989). 
The change from government towards governance may also be explained in 
these terms. A metaphor to gain insight into this change is given in  Figure 1. 
This metaphor is an iterative cyclic process of order and disorder of our com-
plex societal system, but depicted here in two dimensions resulting in four dif-
ferent alternating stages. In stage I the system is in growing disorder and it en-
deavours to find a new order by integration and combination of existing ele-
ments and procedures. In stage II a new order is optimised by central co-
ordination and control mechanisms what we may denote as 'government'. 
When there is too much co-ordination and control, the system loses its effec-
tiveness and stage. III is entered. This means a new period of growing disorder, 
in which government loses (most of) its grip and disintegrates, until finally in 
stage IV a new order is crystallizing out based on differentiation and separation. 
The emphasis of this new order is evidently on 'governance' and not 'govern-
ment'. 
According to the metaphor of  Figure 1 periodic restructuring of a societal 
system will in general result in a higher level of complexity than existed previ-
ously. Periodic restructuring of society in general increases system complexity. 
This may explain why certain planning tools worked quite satisfactory 30-40 
years ago, but are unable to solve today's problems. Evidently, planning meth- 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning 
197 
odology of a centralized system cannot cope with planning problems of decen-
tralized systems and vice versa. 
Figure 1 
Phases of societal system evolution 
Decentralized System 
Emphasis on Governance 
GROWING 
GROWING 
ORDER 
DISORDER 
IV. 
Integration 
Differentiation 
GROWING 
GROWING 
DISORDER 
ORDER 
Emphasis on Government 
Centralized System 
Source:  Own construction. 
An intriguing question is in which stage our society currently is. Albeit diffi-
cult to answer, intuition suggests that many countries in Central and Eastern 
Europe may now be situated in stage III given the collapse of the centralized 
socialist government system. Western Europe may be depicted in stage IV, 
given the growing interest in many fields for governance rather than govern-
ment, as mentioned before. It is more difficult to position the United States. 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
198 
H. Voogd 
This society is witnessing a very strong market-oriented local democracy and 
its planning practice seems a decade ahead' on Europe in many respects, at 
least given its earlier attention for consensus building, mediation practice, pub-
lic-private partnerships, project-oriented planning, and so on. This could imply 
that they have reached again stage I. 
But how valid is the metaphor of Figure 1? Can the evolution of a complex 
system be so simple as it is suggested here? Or does this metaphor only repre-
sent the past, and will the future be less predictive? Evidently, in recent years 
we can see in many societal activities simultaneous opposite developments, 
such as localization and globalisation, and decentralization and centralization as 
well as differentiation and integration  (Partidcirio—Voogd,  1997). New infor-
mation, communication and manufacturing technologies that were inconceiv-
able a few decades ago have made long established and unquestioned functions, 
skills and boundaries obsolete. Also, geographical boundaries are for many 
activities hardly or no barriers anymore. But in contrast to the decreasing im-
portance of boundaries, we see the resurgence of regionalism both in Europe 
and the United States. The region is becoming an increasingly important point 
of reference in the face of globalisation and the changing socio-economic im-
portance of the national-state  (Horvcith,  1994). Evidently, we can now see 
forces at work pulling in opposite directions simultaneously. As  Wannop 
(1995) also has illustrated, there are many different socio-political and histori-
cal contexts in which regional planning nowadays takes place. This again con-
firms the complexity of regional governance systems modern regional planning 
has to cope with. 
Regional governance and the network paradigm 
Understanding regional governance involves both grasping the functioning of 
relevant regional and local institutions, the changing role of government and the 
operation of 'networks', both public and private, which attempt to co-ordinate 
policy areas. If regional governance is defined as the patterns that emerge from 
the policy-making activities of political, administrative and societal actors on a 
regional level, the use of a 'network' metaphor is obvious. According to Kenis 
and Schneider (1991, 25) the term 'network' has become 'the new paradigm for 
the architecture of complexity'. 
The  network  paradigm has gained recognition in social, political and eco-
nomic sciences as the theoretical basis for examining governance structures. A 
social network may include as 'nodes' a wide variety of actors: people, firms 
I  Obviously, in view of Figure 1 'ahead' does not necessarily mean 'better' ! 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning 
199 
and other institutions. Between these 'nodes' different relationships can be 
distinguished. In network theory links, connections and interactions are seen 
especially essential. A network invites different kind of analysis. A rough dis-
tinction can be made between applications that focus on a quantitative, more 
formal, treatment of network structures  (Wasserman—Faust,  1994;  Wasserman-
Galaskiewicz,  1994), and a more qualitative approach focusing on an under-
standing of the dynamics of policy-making processes  (Scharpf  1973;  Rhodes, 
1990;  Teisman,  1992;  Klijn  et al. 1995,  Klein,  1996). Especially the latter ap-
proach appears to be useful for understanding the mechanisms, possibilities and 
limitations of regional planning  (Kasim,  1994, Elander,  1995). 
A regional social network is becoming a regional  planning network  if it is 
used for selectively involving and activating certain actors. Such a planning 
network can be typified by the following components  (Hufen—Ringeling,  1990): 
—A set of actors (individuals, groups, institutions); 
—The interests, wishes and goals of these actors; 
—The activities and problem fields, with regard to the actors have interests 
and/or goals; 
—The rules, norms and assumptions that determine the actions of, and in-
teractions between the actors; 
—The set of action and interaction possibilities of each actor; 
—The set of expected outcomes, costs and benefits of each action and inter-
action. 
The interactions in a regional planning network are varied in nature  (Mar-
tins,  1986). It can involve  resources transfer that is the exchange and/or ap-
propriation of resources between actors. Another type of interactions is called 
volatile communications (Scharpf  1978). These include offers, demands, com-
mands and their acceptance. Some interactions can be explained in terms of 
organisational mobilisation of bias. By this it is meant that administrative rou-
tines tend consistently to favour certain actors at the expense of others. This 
can bear the danger that it operates not only in terms of favouring certain actors 
to the detriment of others, but also in terms of concentrating attention on certain 
problems and solutions to the detriment of others  (Martins,  1986). 
Planning networks are seldomly stable. Dependent on the problem, each 
time new partners and new linkages are created and old linkages are weakened. 
For instance, investors have to be interested and attracted, which involves a 
different pattern of relationships then after the investment has occurred. Hence, 
a network is dynamic. Unlike classical regional development theories which 
share a state-centric conception based on a regional, national or supranational 
authority for hierarchical co-ordination in public policy-making, planning net-
works may even be used to conceptualise and operationalise the form of 'goy- 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
200 
H. Voogd 
ernance without government'  (Rosenau,  1992). This form may be effective if a 
network has sufficient self-regulating power  (Krawinkel,  1997). 
Regional planning involves the recognition and management of a network 
structure that can be roughly visualized like. It will help planners to realize that 
not the government but other actors may have the decisive power to induce 
desired changes. It is therefore essential for a regional planning authority to 
know who the major actors are and how they are interrelated both in terms of 
goals and in terms of means, including restrictive conditions. This enables a 
planning authority to initiate or stimulate effective bargaining or mediation 
processes  (Healey,  1997). 
However, regional governance not necessarily implies the involvement of a 
planning authority. It is not expected that all public decisions be prepared by 
planning. If theorists of governance, such as  Rhodes  (1996), be right we must 
expect for the coming years both more social fragmentation and attempts by 
central authorities to retain control, as well as the emergence of new inter-or-
ganisational networks striving to overcome problems of service delivery and 
co-ordination. Networks may emerge that are essentially 'non-geographical', 
i.e. not limited to a certain area or region, in which different actors involved in 
formulation and implementation of policy co-ordinate their interests through 
so-called 'non-hierarchical bargaining'  (McAleavey,  1993;  Bressers et al. 1994; 
Schneider—Dang-Nguyen—Werle,  1994). Networks that are active on a regional 
level will most probably include public and private partners, therefore fitting a 
general trend towards 'greater permeability of public and private-sector 
boundaries'  (Stoker,  1996). 
Regional governance and collaborative planning 
Governance implies co-operation of stakeholders.  Patsy Healey  (1987) has 
developed a collaborative planning approach to the design of governance sys-
tems and practices, focusing on ways of fostering communicative, consensus-
building practices. In her book, she addresses governance processes and the 
challenge of institutional design for collaborative planning.  Healey  distin-
guishes two levels, the 'soft infrastructure' of practices for developing and 
maintaining particular strategies in specific places and the 'hard infrastructure' 
of the rules and resource of policy systems. 
The 'soft infrastructure' rests on communicative action theory  (Innes,  1995). 
Point of departure of this theory is the assumption that reality is socially con-
structed rather than that 'facts' can be known. Its epistemology is based on 
multiple forms of understanding that should be investigated through discourses. 
Communicative planning may take many forms of which communication, per- 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning 
201 
suasion, learning, mediation, negotiation and bargaining are essential ingredi-
ents  (Forester,  1989;  Susskind—Cruikshank,  1987). 
No doubt, effective communication is crucial for good governance. Evi-
dently, information distribution alone does not qualify as communicating with 
the public, for it is merely a one-way flow. Communication involves two-way 
relations whereby both sides can share the facts and voice views. In this light, 
extra steps must be taken in order to create venues for allowing stakeholders to 
communicate.  Friedmann (1973) already pointed out that (transactive) planning 
deals with much dialogue, mutual discovery, acceptance of conflict, shared 
interests and commitment, and reciprocity and mutual obligation. 
It is obvious that participation of a variety of stakeholders is essential to 
learn about community values and problems, and for avoiding unnecessary 
conflicts by making community members feel comfortable with the way the 
process is conducted 2. In the previous section it has been mentioned that plan-
ning networks should encourage civic engagement of stakeholders. These net-
works help to facilitate co-ordination and communication, while amplifying 
information about the trustworthiness of other actors. However, there is some 
evidence that networks will be less intense and declining in larger communities, 
such as regions. For instance, in his research on the decline of social capital, 
Putnam  (1995) discovered that networks in larger communities are less bal-
anced 'centres of discourse' than they are in small communities. This may be a 
weakness of regional governance (for a more elaborate discussion of commu-
nicative/collaborative planning: see  Voogd—Woltjer,  1999). 
Regional governance and social dilemmas 
A fundamental problem of collaborative planning, and hence of governance, is 
the existence of so-called  social dilemmas (Voogd,  1995, 1999a). A social di-
lemma is a conflict between the choice an actor would make to maximize its 
self-interest and the choice that would be best for the collective. In planning we 
are often confronted with situations in which private interests are at odds with 
public interests. A classical example is Hardin's 'Tragedy of the Commons' 
2  The term 'community' is not unambiguous. Traditionally, the term refers to a set of people 
living in the same locality in which at least some resources are shared. Yet today, communities 
can range geographically from neighbourhoods to small rural hamlets to regional or even global 
scales. The term also connotes other definitions of an abstract nature in which physical bounda-
ries are no longer implied (e.g. the Internet community'). In our mobile societies, it is possible to 
share resources with many different people in different places and thus be a member of many 
communities. 'Community', therefore, has become a loose concept; it is no longer a self-con-
tained entity which can be easily defined. 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
202 
H. Voogd 
(Hardin,  1968). He describes how individual farmers have access to grazing 
grounds that are held in common by all. Each can make a personal profit by 
adding successive cattle to the commons and each continues to do so. Adding 
an extra animal implies costs in terms of pasture consumed, but these costs are 
consumed by the collectivity. A tragedy comes into being because every farmer 
is inclined to increase his own herd, while leaving the costs involved to the 
collectivity. But, as this process continues, as a result far greater costs are likely 
to be generated than individually absorbed benefits. Ultimately the commons 
will be destroyed. This is an example of a group of individuals who are faced 
with the problem of how to maintain their collective good and who — if they 
give in to their individual 'greed' — actually produce a collective undesired 
product. 
In order to prevent such an undesired collective situation, individuals have 
to restraint themselves. This is not an easy affair. Any individual in the above 
situation may consider two possibilities. First, if others do exercise restraint, 
one can personally enjoy the fruits of their restraint without having to contrib-
ute to its costs. That is, by being a so-called 'free-rider', one profits from the 
fact that others prevent the collective bad situation. Second, one may consider 
the possibility of being a 'sucker' who incurs a cost when nobody else does, 
perhaps ending up carrying the total cost. But why should one do this? 
The implications of this behaviour can have far reaching effects for all as-
pects of life. Jay Forrester researched this phenomenon in the 1970s. His fa-
mous study of 'system dynamics' led him to believe that some of the causes of 
pressing public issues are grounded in the very politics to solve them. These 
policies are too often the result of superficiality and social acceptability, which 
devise interventions that focus on obvious symptoms, not the underlying 
causes. The problem is that this produces short-term benefit, with little or no 
improvement in the long run.  Forrester (1971) illustrated that when more 
symptomatic interventions are needed and used, a cycle begins with detrimental 
consequences. 
Different types of social dilemmas can be distinguished, for instance based 
on the number of people in the group, the nature of contributions (continuous or 
once-only), the nature of rewards or utility (proportional or step), jointness of 
supply, and so on  (Axelrod,  1984). An interesting distinction of social dilem-
mas from a planning point of view relates to the quality of the initial collective 
situation, viz. the  maintenance  of a public good and the  provision  of a public 
good, respectively. The social dilemma of Hardin's metaphor refers to dilem-
mas in which the initial situation is desirable from a collective point of view. 
But it asks for costly individual actions to keep it desirable, in other words, to 
maintain the current situation. Examples are all around us: the protection of our 
cultural heritage, nature areas, historic town centres, and so forth. But we can 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning 
203 
also distinguish situations where the initial situation is an undesirable one: 
derelict land, heavily polluted areas, areas with urban blight, etc. This demands 
costly individual actions to make the situation desirable from a collective point 
of view. 
Research from social psychologists, however, revealed no fundamental dif-
ference between the behaviour of actors in 'take some games', directed towards 
maintenance of a public good, and 'give some games', focussing on the provi-
sion of a public good  (Rutte  et al. 1987). This suggests that in both perspectives 
actors be inclined to burden others with the costs of the maintenance or the 
provision of collective goods. 
Social dilemmas are products of rational thinking. Rational thinking means 
that a utility framework is used for analysing and understanding actors and 
processes. According to such framework an action is rational if it has the high-
est utility of all options  recognised. Here it is assumed that a utility framework 
does not necessarily require that the information available is correct and ex-
haustive. If an action is based on a utility assessment of erroneous information, 
it still remains a rational action. Evidently, social dilemmas can be easily theo-
retically 'removed' by rejecting this interpretation of rationality. But if it is 
accepted that actors do not behave rationally, why should we embrace govern-
ance based on collaborative planning? Why should 'irrational' behaving actors 
accept a governance system, which is also intrinsically based on a utility (`win-
win') framework? 
Hardin (1968) expressed the belief that social dilemmas can only be solved 
by some kind of mutual restraint and that solutions which do appeal to individ-
ual co-operation are doomed to be unsuccessful. Research of social psycholo-
gists into this matter did show that in general an actor has a strong reluctance to 
hand over one's decisional freedom to a superimposed authority  (Wilke  et al. 
1986;  Rutte  et al. 1987). This reluctance can be overcome, however, when one 
is sufficiently compensated. A certain loss of control is accepted when faced 
with a situation in which there is a thread of a collective catastrophe or when 
there are large social discrepancies in the allocation of outcomes. These results, 
derived from psychological gaming, suggest that the framing of a situation as 
one in which large inequalities or an impending catastrophe is at stake, will 
make decision-making by a superimposed authority acceptable. 
Given these opinions and research results, it would be a logical next step to 
proclaim government as a superimposed authority that should solve social di-
lemmas. However, this is less obvious as it may seem. It depends on the quality 
of government whether they are willing and able to recognise social dilemmas 
and whether they want to act accordingly. This recognition of social dilemmas 
by the government is very important, especially if we acknowledge the results 
of psychological research that in case of social dilemmas  voluntary co-opera- 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
204 
H. Voogd 
tion alone does not work  (Rutte  et al. 1987). For example, we know that there is 
little chance of successful environmental voluntary action by citizens due to the 
social dilemma phenomenon. Environmental planning can never be successful 
without a government enforcing rules and constraints. Heritage planning would 
be a failure if it would only depend on voluntary sacrifices; the provision and 
preservation of a broad spectrum of culture cannot carry on without the support 
of government. Health care facilities, high quality public transport, etc. would 
never reach the thinly populated periphery of a country without national and 
regional government support, and so forth. 'Here' will always be more impor-
tant than 'there', and 'now' more important that 'then', if the masses have to 
decide  (Vlek—Keren,  1992). These observations support the conclusion that the 
importance of the role of government, being the most important actor for solv-
ing social dilemmas, must not be neglected in regional governance. 
Regional governance and government 
There is no question that for ethical, political and 'marketing' reasons 'bottom-
up' regional governance, as reflected in participatory, communicative, collabo-
rative, etc. planning, are much to be preferred to 'top-down' government. 
However, as outlined in the previous section, certain social dilemmas call for 
`top-down' government. This problem is usually dealt with by introducing the 
subsidiarity principle,  which means that the decision-making authority should 
reside at the level most appropriate to the problem being addressed. 3  Unfortu-
nately, this is not an unambiguous criterion, as discussions in and about the 
European Union clearly illustrate  (CEC,  1992;  Toulemonde,  1996;  Merkel—
Heinz,  
1997). 
With respect to the role of the superimposed authority, three elements 
should be distinguished. The first element concerns the level at which authority 
should be vested for specific policy areas. Which tasks should be delegated to a 
regional government or regional co-operative? This relates to the well-known 
debate over centralization and decentralization  (Eichenberger,  1994). Decen-
tralization can allow government to respond more effectively to variations in 
local needs and preferences; to lower costs of planning and administration; 
provide opportunities and incentives for policy innovation; and give citizens 
greater choice and voice in policymaking. Centralization, on the other hand, 
3  In the Treaty on the European Union, Article 3b, it is described as: "In areas which are not 
under its exclusive power, the Community shall act in conformity with the principle of subsidiar-
ity, only if and in so far as the objectives of the proposed action cannot be sufficiently achieved 
by the member states and can therefore, by reason of the scale and efforts of the proposed action 
be better achieved by the Community". 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning 
205 
enables government to address problems having cross-border (or spillover) 
effects; protect consumers against product risks; exploit available economies of 
scale; co-ordinate policies more effectively; and promote equality and political 
homogeneity across a larger domain to reflect 'shared values'. The theoretical 
advantages of centralization and decentralization counterbalance each other, 
suggesting that the precise nature of an optimal allocation of authority may 
prove to be highly context-dependent. The second element regards the question 
of how intrusive policy-making of a regional authority should be. Evidently, it 
should not render superfluous local policymaking. Clearly, the demands and 
needs of local stakeholders must be addressed. The third element addresses the 
question of how individual stakeholders can retain some control over a policy 
area that is delegated to the regional authority. This calls for dialogues in a 
network context. 
These dialogues might be most effectively promoted by the rules suggested 
by Healey (1997, 297), i.e.: 
—By broadly-based rights of voice and influence for concerned people; 
—By provisions to ensure that all parties who can demonstrate a stake in an 
issue have the opportunity to challenge decisions in superimposed arenas; 
—By a right to good quality information available to all parties to assist 
them to consider what is a stake; 
—By a right available to all parties to call any governance agency, formal or 
informal, to account for failure, with respect to the duties and 
responsibilities which apply to the exercise of responsibilities of the 
superimposed authority. 
A Dutch experience: regional transportation governance 
Regional governance, especially of urban regions, is often seen as a problem in 
the Netherlands. All urban regions in the Netherlands have multiple govern-
mental authorities. For the seven largest urban regions (In Dutch:  kaderwet 
gebieden)  
'umbrella' organisations now exist, that covers the entire regions. 
But these organisations are not founded on direct public elections, which means 
that their democratic legitimacy is often questioned. Their power is therefore 
limited. 
Regional public transport may also be subdivided between different institu-
tions. Although a Bus Company has more or less a monopoly in its own spe-
cific work area, a region is often served by more than one Bus Company. Co-
ordination between Bus Companies appears to be not always an easy task, be-
cause there is no formal need to communicate and co-operate. In addition, the 
Dutch Railway Company is an important actor. This is an independent privat- 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
206 
H. Voogd 
ized organisation, whose prime interest is  not  'how to serve the region best' but 
`how to survive without a deficit'  (Voogd,  1999b). 
In order to improve regional institutional co-ordination, the Dutch govern-
ment introduced in 1988 in her strategic national transport plan, the so-called 
Structure Scheme on Traffic and Transportation, a new concept. This concept 
was called the  Transport Regions  (see also Kerstens, 1998). It was advocated 
that urban regions should develop a specific regional co-ordinating institution, 
including both public and private stakeholders, for realizing an integrated re-
gional traffic and transportation policy. Because of the national funding in-
volved, within a few years time almost 30 Transport Regions were created. 
Although the initiative was 'top-down', the resulting process was clearly a vol-
untary 'bottom-up' process. Hence, Transport Regions had different organisa-
tional structures and types of participants. Most often, the following actors 
were involved: the municipal authorities, the province, representatives from 
national ministry for traffic and transportation, Bus Companies, the Dutch 
Railway Company, and the Chamber of Commerce. 
Unfortunately, the Transport Regions never became a success  (Kerstens, 
1998). A very, if not most, important factor was that the national government 
did not adequately support her own initiative  (Hensing,  1993). At the same time 
that the Ministry of Traffic and Transportation introduced the Transport Re-
gion, the Ministry of Interior Affairs worked on a new administrative structure 
for the Netherlands, especially directed towards an improvement of the admin-
istrative structure of urban agglomerations. This evoked a lot of discussion. It 
soon appeared that only a very few (ultimately seven) Transport Regions were 
also nominated for a special administrative regional status, in between a mu-
nicipal and a provincial status. The other Transport Regions felt more of less 
abandoned by the Dutch government, which killed this promising initiative. 
Without national support, there was no impetus for a voluntary continuation of 
this regional governance initiative. 
It is interesting to remark here that initially the 'bottom-up' process of cre-
ating Transport Regions was very successful. This raises the question, why 
different public and private participants were so eager to co-operate for 
realising an integrated regional policy. Unfortunately, the answer is rather 
down-to-earth: they expected a financial reward! It was also this reason that a 
number of Transport Regions did not function very well, because of internal 
conflicts about the division of funds that were not, not yet, or only very limited 
available (Hensing,  1993). 
Another problem of institutional co-operation appeared to be the different 
`cultures' of the actors involved. Governmental officials sometimes complained 
that representatives of, for instance, Bus Companies were hardly willing, or 
able, to think in more strategic terms than the level of a time-schedule of a bus. 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning 
207 
This hampered the quality of the debates and the consensus-building process 
(Hensing,  1993). 
Besides this institutional approach of regional governance, also procedural 
solutions have been offered to improve a co-ordinated regional planning. As a 
result of the failure of the Transport Regions, the National Government entered 
a discussion with representatives of municipalities and provinces about new 
procedures for regional transport planning. Special attention was given to the 
funding problem, since this was the major issue for municipal and provincial 
authorities. It was decided to have a redistribution of some parts of the national 
infrastructure fund to provinces and municipalities for improving regional 
transport planning and traffic safety. This was justified by pointing at the 
subsidiarity principle discussed before. In 1997 a covenant was signed between 
the national government, provinces and municipalities about the decentraliza-
tion of national traffic and transport tasks and related funding. In return, it was 
agreed upon a further formalization of the transport planning structure in a 
sense that regional traffic and transportation plans should be made in order to 
guide decision-making and future investments. 
How should we judge this development in the light of the governance-gov-
ernment debate? The positive view is that plan making enables public discus-
sion, provided that a pro-active institutional and citizens involvement is stimu-
lated. It offers, however, no guarantee that, for instance, land use and transpor-
tation policies are consistently geared to one another. On the contrary, in prac-
tice it may imply a strengthening of the transport sector and hence a strength-
ening of 'narrow minded' sectorial viewpoints, which may enhance, rather than 
narrowing down, the gap between land use and transport planning. 
A Dutch experience: covenants 
The agreement with respect to the redistribution of national infrastructure funds 
illustrates an important procedural development, which is significant for gov-
ernance. This concern the use of  covenants,  being voluntary agreements based 
on a consensus-building process between various actors involved  (Voogd, 
1999b). In Dutch environmental planning covenants are regarded as an effec-
tive instrument that better reflects the joint responsibility of the government 
and industry for environmental improvement  (Bertels—Kranendonk,  1996). The 
intensive consultation that precedes the signing of covenants, allows the gov-
ernment to obtain a better understanding of the possibilities and barriers to en-
vironmental improvement in industry, and to adapt goals, legislation and sup-
port realistically. These discussions also provide an opportunity to create in-
creased awareness of environmental problems among industry representatives. 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
208 
H. Voogd 
The use of covenants in environmental planning is not without problems 
(Bertels—Kranendonk,  1996). Actors that do not want to join in the negotiations 
or withdraw from them, undermine the results and morale of the operation. Bad 
public acceptability is another problem. Voluntary agreements have received a 
bad image in the press because, since the negotiations between authorities and 
industry were held behind closed doors and not controlled by Parliament, the 
suspicion arose that government representatives were being lobbied and other-
wise influenced by industrial interests. 
Environmental groups, while they see a use for covenants, are showing some 
fear that covenants may engender prolonged deterioration of the environment 
because companies are using them to slow the process of environmental im-
provement  (Bertels—Kranendonk,  1996). They therefore suggest improving the 
performance of voluntary agreements by making them one element within a 
broader package of instruments, which should also include sanctions and direct 
regulation in the case of non-compliance. In other words, what is needed is a 
`stick behind the door'  (Houtsma,  1994). 
Covenants have also been important for the implementation of national 
physical planning policy. In the Fourth Report on Physical Planning (1988), and 
its renewed version, the Fourth Report on Physical Planning Extra (1992) —
abbreviated in Dutch as Vinex — much attention was paid to locations for new 
large-scale neighbourhoods. These locations, called  Vinex-locations,  have all 
been situated within existing urban agglomerations. A main reason was that 
such locations would stimulate the use of public transport. However, this also 
raised quite a few problems, because most sites were not easy to develop due to 
their spatial characteristics (e.g. former wasteland with contaminated soils 
and/or close to highways or other infrastructure that causes environmental 
problems, such as noise nuisance or safety problems). Additional funding from 
national government was necessary to make these locations attractive enough 
for public investors and developers. It took several years before agreements 
between municipalities and the national government could be written down in 
covenants. 
Covenants are also important instruments for establishing informal regional 
development plans and implementation agreements. A recent example is the 
development plan for the urban region of Groningen. This region has a special 
governance structure, since it is situated in two provinces (Province of Gronin-
gen in the north and the Province of Drenthe in the south) and it consists of 
twelve municipalities. In the past, many voluntary arrangements, among other 
along the lines of the "Transport Region" as described above, failed because of 
competition struggles and the fact that there were two formal regional authori-
ties involved for different parts of the region, viz. the provincial governments of 
Groningen and Drenthe. 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning 
209 
The voluntary regional plan for the urban region of Groningen is an inte-
grated land-use and transportation plan. It is accompanied by an implementa-
tion covenant, stating the agreements about the organisation of the collabora-
tion and the implementation, including the financial contribution of each part-
ner each year for common projects. 
This approach has received both appreciation and critique. The appreciation 
refers to the integrated approach of land-use planning, regional economic plan-
ning and transport planning and the fact that the barrier of provincial bounda-
ries is crossed. The critique especially focuses on the democratic process, or 
more precise, the lack of public and political involvement in the 're-active' 
plan-making process. Municipal councils feel that it is a matter of 'if you don't 
like it, you can lump it'. There is hardly any opportunity for council members 
to change the covenant, since it is the product of an institutional consensus 
building process behind close doors between a few representatives in a 'steer-
ing committee' or alike. On the other hand, many participants will agree that if 
it had been 'pro-active' governance, there would not have been any agreement 
at all. 
Some concluding remarks 
This paper has paid attention to governance and its relationship with regional 
planning. Regional planning is in most countries unmistakable a public sector-
led activity, but comprising both public and private actors. Since regional plan-
ning does not exist in a social vacuum, it has much in common with modern 
ideas about governance. Its outcomes will not only be shaped by discourses and 
power relations internal to the planning network (i.e. 'soft infrastructure' ac-
cording to  Healey,  1997), but also by a variety of contextual constraints: social, 
political, economic, and organisational (i.e. 'hard infrastructure'). These 
constraints are themselves, in part at least, the result of wider power relations, 
including the increasing role of the European Union. 
Regional planning is in essence action-oriented, i.e. it should evoke actions 
to improve spatial and environmental qualities of a region, including social and 
economic conditions, as well as provide a protective framework to prevent a 
deterioration of regional resources. It is argued in this paper that it is unlikely 
that regional governance, without the assistance of regional government as a 
superimposed authority, can handle all these tasks. 'Tailor-made' planning ap-
proaches will be necessary, each beginning by identifying the set of actors in-
volved in the governance process. Network theory shows that it is necessary not 
only to identify which actors are involved, but also to clarify what role each 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
210 
H. Voogd 
actor can play in the process and how they may interact in the planning net-
work. 
Experiences with Dutch regional planning practices show that there should 
be an acknowledgement of the important role of superimposed authorities for 
planning, both as an arena where representatives must balance their delegated 
interests and as an arena were conditions (rules, regulations, plans) are shaped 
for dealing with the interests of stakeholders, for instance in the field of 
sustainable development, heritage protection, and so forth. 
References 
Axelrod, R. 1984:  The Evolution of Co-operation.  New York, Basic Books. 
Bertels, J.—Kranendonk, S. 1996:  The Dutch National Environmental Policy Plans and 
Industry Covenants.  Amsterdam/Wuppertal, Institute for Environmental Studies/ 
Wuppertal Institute. 
Boomsma, H. 1998: Woon-werkverkeer: beleid of toeval. De invloed van het locatie-
beleid op pendelstromen in het woon-werkverkeer. Faculty of Spatial Sciences, Uni-
versity of Groningen. 
Bressers, H.—O'Toole, L. J.—Richardson, J. (eds.) 1994: Networks for Water Policy: A 
Comparative Perspective. —  Environmental Politics.  Special Issue, Vol. 3, 4. 
Cappelin, R.—Batey, P. (eds) 1993: Regional Networks, Border Regions and European 
Integration. London, Pion. 
CEC 1992: Commission of the European Communities, The principle of subsidiarity, 
Communication of the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament, 
SEC (92), Brussels, 27 October 1992. 
De Roo, G. 1999: Planning per Se, Planning per Saldo. The Hague, SDU. 
Healey, P. 1997: Collaborative Planning: Shaping Places in Fragmented Societies. 
London, Macmillan. 
Dutch Parliament 1993: Vervoerregio's: regionaal verkeers-en vervoersbeleid, Tweede 
Kamer der Staten-Generaal, vergaderjaar 1992-1993, 23 198 nr. 1, SDU uitgeverij, 
Den Haag. 
Eichenberger, R. 1994: The Benefits of Federalism and the Risk of Overcentralization.  — 
Kyklos  47. 
Forrester, J. W. 1971:  World Dynamics.  Cambridge, Mass, Wright—Allen Press. 
Forrester, J. 1989:  Planning in the Face of Power. Los Angeles, University of California 
Press. 
Friedmann, J. 1973:  Retracking America: a Theory of Transactive Planning.  Garden 
City NY, Anchor Press/Doubleday. 
Glasson, J. 1974:  An Introduction to Regional Planning.  London, Hutchinson. 
Hardin, G. R. 1968: The tragedy of the commons. —  Science.  162. 
Harding, A. 1994: Urban regimes and growth machines: towards a cross-national 
agenda. —  Urban Affairs Quarterly.  29. 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning 
211 
Hensing, H. F. 1993: De vervoerregio — een compromis in balans? Faculty of Spatial 
Sciences, University of Groningen. 
Hilhorst, J. G. M. 1967: Regional Development Theory, An Attempt to Synthesise. The 
Hague, Mouton: 
Hilhorst, J. G. M. 1971:  Regional Planning. Rotterdam, Rotterdam University Press. 
Horvath, Gy. 1994: From the micro-regionalisation to the research of the co-operation of 
the European Regions. — Hajdd, Z.—Horvath, Gy. (eds):  European Challenges and 
Hungarian Responses in Regional Policy.  
Pecs, Centre for Regional Studies, Hun-
garian Academy of Sciences. 
Houtsma, W. H. 1994: Het herenakkoord als reflex. —  Milieudefensie.  2. 
Hufen, J. A. M.—Ringeling, A. B. (eds) 1990:  Beleidsnetwerken.  Den Haag, Vuga. 
Innes, J. 1995: Planning Theory's Emerging Paradigm: Communicative Action and 
Interactive Practice. —  Journal of Planning Education and Research. 1. 
Kassim, H. 1994: Policy Networks, Networks and European Union Policy Making: A 
Sceptical View. —  West European Politics.  4. 
Krawinkel, M. 1997:  Nieuw voegwerk voor de wijk.  Maastricht, Shaker Publishing. 
Kennedy, P. 1989:  The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers. New York, Vintage Books. 
Klijn, E. H. 1996: Analyzing and Managing Policy Processes in Complex Networks: A 
Theoretical Examination of the Concept Policy Network and Its Problems. —  Admini- 
stration and Society.  1. 
Klijn, E. H. —J. Koppenjan—Termeer, K. 1995: Managing networks in the public sector: 
A theoretical study of management strategies in policy networks. —  Public Admini-
stration.  
3. 
Kuhn, T. S. 1969:  The Structure of Scientific Revolutions.  Chicago, The University of 
Chicago Press. 
Linstone, H. A. 1996: Technological Slowdown or Societal Speedup — The Price of 
Complexity? —  Technological Forecasting and Social Change. 2. 
Linstone, H. A. —Mitroff, I. I. 1994:  The Challenge of the 21st Century.  Albany, State of 
New York University Press. 
Martins, M. R. 1986: An Organisational Approach to Regional Planning. Aldershot, 
Gower. 
McAleavey, P. 1993: The Politics of European Regional Development Policy: Addi-
tionality in the Scottish Coalfields. — Regional Politics and Policy.  3. 
Menkel, W. —Heinz, I. 1997: Standards in the water sector; the principle of subsidiarity 
and the role of cost-benefit analysis. —  Water Supply.  4. 
Molle, W.—Cappelin, R. (eds) 1988:  Regional Impact of Community Policies in Europe. 
Aldershot, Gower. 
Partidario, M.—Voogd, H. 1999: An endeavour at integration in environmental analysis 
and planning — D. Miller—de Roo, G. (eds):  Integrating City Planning and Environ-
mental Improvement.  
Aldershot, Ashgate. 
Putnam, R. D. 1995: Bowling alone: America's decline in social capital. —  Journal of 
Democracy.  Vol. 10. 
Rhodes, R. A. W. 1990: Policy Networks. A British Perspective. —  Journal of Theo-
retical Politics. 3. 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
212 
H. Voogd 
Rhodes, R. A. W. 1996: The new governance: governing without government. —  Politi-
cal Studies.  2. 
Rosenau, J. 1992: Governance, Order, and Change in World Politics. — Rosenau, J. N. — 
Czempiel, E. (eds.):  Governance Without Government: Order and Change in World 
Politics.  
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. 
Rutte, C. G.—Wilke, H. A. M.—Messick, D. M. 1987: The effects of framing social di-
lenunas as give some or take some games. —  British Journal of Social Psychology. 
26. 
Scharpf, F. 1978: Interorganisational policy studies: issues, concepts and perspectives. — 
Hanf, K.—Scharpf, F. (eds):  Interorganisational Policy-Making: limits to co-
ordination and central control. 
London, Sage. 
Self, P. 1980: Whatever Happened to Regional Planning? —  Town and Country Plan-
ning.  4. 
Schneider, V.—Dang-Nguyen, G.—Werle, R. 1994: Corporate Actor Network in Euro-
pean Policy-Making:.  Harmonizing Telecommunications Policy. —  Journal of Com-
mon Market Studies.  
4. 
Stoker, G.—Mossberger, K. 1994: Urban regime theory in comparative perspective. 
12. 
—Environment and Planning C. 
Susskind, L.—Cruikshank, J. 1987: Breaking the Impasse: Consensual Approaches to 
Resolving Public Disputes. New York, Basic Books. 
Teisman, G. R. 1992: Complexe Besluitvorming, een pluricentrisch perspectief op 
besluitvorming over ruimtelijke investeringen; VUGA, 's-Gravenhage. 
Urey, W.—Brett, J.—Goldberg, S. 1988: Getting Disputes Resolved: Designing Systems 
to Cut the Costs of Conflict. Jossey-B ass Publishers. 
Thornley, A.—Newman, P. 1996: International competition, urban governance and 
planning projects: Malmo, Birmingham and Lille. —  European Planning Studies. 4. 
Toulemonde, J. 1996: Can we evaluate subsidiarity? Elements of answers from the 
European practice. —  International review of administrative sciences.  1. 
Vlek, C. A. J.—Keren, G. B. 1992: Behavioral decision theory and environmental risk 
management: assessment and resolution of four 'survival' dilemmas. —  Acta Psycho-
logica.  
1. 
Voogd, H. 1995: Environmental management of social dilemmas. —  European Spatial 
Research and Policy.  1. 
Voogd, H. 1999a: Social dilemmas and the communicative planning paradox. —  Town 
Planning Review.  (Forthcoming.) 
Voogd, H. I 999b: Co-ordination between land-use planning and transportation planning, 
Report prepared for COST Action 332 of the European Commission, Directorate 
General Transport, and presented at the Colloquium of the Swiss Federal Institute of 
Technology Lausanne, 10-12 February 1999. 
Voogd, H.—Woltjer, J. 1999: The communicative ideology in spatial planning: some 
critical reflections based on Dutch experiences.  Environment and Planning B. 
(Forthcoming.) 
Wilke, H. A. M.—Liebrand, W. B. G.—de Boer, K. 1986: Standards of justice and quality 
of power in a social dilemma situation. —  British Journal of Social Psychology.  16. 

Henk Voogd : Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning. In: Role of the Regions 
in the Enlarging European Union. Pécs, Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 194-213. p. 
Discussion Papers. Special 
Rethinking Regional Governance and Planning 
213 
Woltjer, J. 1999: Consensus planning and Dutch infrastructure policy. PhD, University 
of Groningen, Groningen. 
Wannop, U. A. 1995: The Regional Imperative, Regional Planning and Governance in 
Britain, Europe and the United States. London, Jessica Kingsley. 
Wasserman, S.—Faust, K. 1994:  Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications. 
Cambridge/New York, Cambridge University Press. 
Wasserman, S.—Galaskiewicz, J. 1994: Advances in Social Network Analysis: Research 
From the Social and Behavioral Sciences. Newbury Park, Sage.