Discussion Papers 2001. No. 35. 
Regional Development and Governance in Hungary
CENTRE FOR REGIONAL STUDIES 
OF HUNGARIAN ACADEMY OF SCIENCES 
DISCUSSION PAPERS 
No. 35 
Regional Development and Governance 
in Hungary 
by 
Ilona PALNE KOVACS 
Series editor 
Zoltan GAL 
Pecs 
2001 

Discussion Papers 2001. No. 35. 
Regional Development and Governance in Hungary 
Publishing of this paper is supported by the 
Research and Publishing Fund of the Centre for Regional Studies, Hungary 
ISSN 0238-2008 
2000 by Centre for Regional Studies of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences 
Technical editor: Ilona Csape, Zoltan Gal 
Typeset by Centre for Regional Studies of HAS Printed in Hungary by Siimegi 
Nyomdaipari, Kereskedelmi es Szolgaltato Ltd., Pecs 

Discussion Papers 2001. No. 35. 
Regional Development and Governance in Hungary 
Contents 
1 The legal frameworks of the decentralisation / 7 
2 The structure of the model / 9 
2.1 Fragmented municipalities / 
2.2 Weak meso-tier  /10 
2.3 Expanding deconcentrated state administration  /13 
2.4 Lack of associations  /15 
3 The regional development policy before 1996 /  19 
4 Reform of the local governmental system in 1994  /21 
4.1 Slow integration / 21 
4.2 Ambivalent strengthening of county assemblies / 23 
4.3 Careful steps towards the integration of territorial state administration /  24 
5 The act on regional development in 1996  /25 
5.1 The regulation  /25 
5.2 The first experiences of functioning of the regional policy  /30 
6 The agenda of the territorial reforms  /32 
6.1 Reform alternatives for territorial division to replace the "too small" or 
"too large" counties  /33 
6.2 The failure of the reform debates — Concealment of political aspects  /34 
7 The story since 1998 — the regionalisation — ultimate chance? /  36 
References / 40 

Discussion Papers 2001. No. 35. 
Regional Development and Governance in Hungary 
List of Tables 
Table 1 Main data on local governments 1 January 1992, 1998, 2000  /11 
Table 2 Number and population of settlements by population size-groups, 
1 January 1997 and 2000  /11 
Table 3 
Number of the settlements (districts) participating in 
associations (1992)  /16 
Table 4 Number of settlements (districts) participating in associations 
(1999)  / 16 
Table 5 Situation of micro-regional development associations in 1994 /  17 
Table 6 Situation of micro-regional development associations in 1999 / 17 
Table 7 Local government budgets as % of total incomes between 
1993-1999 /23 
List of Figures 
Figure 1 Map of public administration in Hungary  /12 
Figure 2 Central and Regional Public Administration in Hungary in 1994 /  14 
Figure 3 Central and Regional Public Administration in Hungary in 1998  / 26 
Figure 4 The key organisations of regional development in Hungary  /28 
Figure 5 Various designations of the regions in Hungary  /31 




Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
1 The legal frameworks of the decentralisation 
Following the systemic change the first really significant legal document passed by 
the newly elected parliament was the Act on Local Governments. The preparation 
of the Act progressed in the crossfire of serious political debates, since all political 
groups realised that the act will fundamentally impact the future power exercise. 
Despite of the number of amendments and debates the act was passed with a sig-
nificant majority. 
The Act meets international standards as far as its spirit and liberalism are con-
cerned and at the same time, has brought a dramatic change in the structure of 
Hungarian public administration. The Act declares the right to self-governance, as 
the collective right of citizens living within one locality, therefore  the settlement 
became the key element in the local government system.  
It is conspicuous in both 
the Act on Local Governments and the Constitution that the legislature strove at 
creating the guarantees of the local governments' autonomy in terms of structure 
and decision-making. This is reflected by the enumeration of the basic rights of 
local governments, the declaration of equity in terms of their legal status. The 
regulation of the relationship to the state as well as the weak control of lawfulness 
over the local governments seem to point to the fact that  the essence of the Hun-
garian self-governmental model is autonomy and independence from state influ-
ence and hierarchy.  
The choice of value by the legislator in relation to the local 
government model was mainly motivated by political intentions, and therefore 
besides the guarantees of democracy and independence the aspects of efficiency 
and the public administrative rationality were rather neglected.  (Stewart, J.—Stoker, 
G.  
1995). Once the structure and labour guarantees thereof prevail, this model can 
provide all advantages. However, legislation and administration following the en-
actment of the Act on Local Governments pointed out that despite of all the liber-
alism of the regulations the model of self-government with its legal guarantees  of 
free decision-making alone can not ensure political and power decentralisation. 
The parliamentary and governmental decisions and measures of the previous years 
in many respects run counter to the original logic of self-governance, despite of the 
fact that from the aspect of the legal form there was no interference with the com-
petencies and decisions of the local governments. 
The constitutional guarantees of the basic rights of local governments: 
• The Act on Local Governments declares the relative autonomy of local gov-
ernments, stating that all decisions made on local matters are final and there-
fore can only be revised for lawfulness. The provision stating that local pub-
lic matters can be remitted to other central government offices only in ex-
ceptional cases is of great constitutional importance. This regulation ensures 


Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
the dominance of the local governmental sector within the public admini-
stration. Although the Act on Local Governments stipulates that "local af-
fairs may be delegated to other organisations only exceptionally", no defini-
tion of "local affairs" or their minimal content is provided, therefore no legal 
hindrances are set to limit the expansion of the deconcentrated state admini-
stration. 
• The Act grants great freedom to the local governments to establish organisa-
tions, to pass decrees, join alliances for the protection of common their inter-
ests and other types of associations. 
• The Act defines the compulsory tasks of the local governments, specifying 
the government support they are granted to and indicating that larger local 
governments may be assigned with more tasks. Distinguishing between the 
tasks of local governments and the state administration, the Act provides that 
the tasks of local governments may only be defined by parliamentary acts. 
The liberal spirit of the Act is well illustrated by the fact that it allows a 
fairly liberal distribution of local governmental functions on a voluntary ba-
sis, being obviously more favourable to municipalities versus the counties. 
• The declaration of the equal rights of local governments and the subsidiary 
status of the counties was important for the legislator. This principle put an 
end to the previous, century-long tradition granting more power to the 19 
counties, which used to be the only territorial tier of the Hungarian State. In 
the Soviet-type council system between 1950-1990, the power between the 
representative body and public administration was not divided. The soviet-
type council system incorporated the various tasks from safeguarding of lo-
cal interests, through the supervision of companies and management of 
services, to the administration by public authorities, placing all these under 
the control of elected bodies. The socialist state did not "distrust" county 
councils, which were considered as both the agency of the central state and 
representative of the municipal interests. The central state therefore did not 
care to develop a deconcentrated system of public administration, since it 
had control over the whole mechanism once the territorial governance as a 
whole had been incorporated into the prevailing hierarchy. This means that 
the new model of local government instituted in 1990 inherited a completely 
uniform system of territorial governance. As to this legacy, a further specific 
feature of the previous 40 years is to be mentioned. The Soviet—type council 
system in Hungary functioned not only in a uniform but also in a territorially 
integrated, concentrated organisational mechanism. This was valid for coun-
cils in tiny villages, the districts (settlements in the neighbourhood of towns 
and the towns themselves) and for the administration of towns as well. The 


Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
high level of integration — it was said — improved efficiency and the profi-
ciency of public administration but at the same time, resulted in a huge 
"deficit in democracy" and made representation within the councils just a 
formality. The focal point was the county council controlling the activities of 
local councils in several ways ranging from legal supervision, through the di-
rection of public administration, to acting as a forum of appeal and allocating 
of financial resources and a major investor in the service provision. 
2 The structure of the model 
The above facts led to the mentioned characteristic features of the Hungarian local 
governmental model, which made conscious efforts to eliminate all the compulsory 
and hierarchical aspects of integration. 
There are four aspects in which the Hungarian system of local governments dif-
fers from the Western European trends: too small municipalities, too weak coun-
ties, to large and powerful state sector in the territorial tier and too few associa-
tions. 
2.1 Fragmented municipalities 
As first, due to the aspiration of small villages to absolute self-rule and autonomy 
these local authorities are highly fragmented. The more than three thousand 
autonomous decision-making bodies in the wake of the Act on Local Governments 
replaced formerly integrated 1600 local authorities. Over 35 per cent of the local 
authorities have less than 500 inhabitants. The average-size local government has 
3,400 inhabitants, which is below the European average. There are also countries 
with more fragmented local authority systems in Europe i.e. France and Greece, 
Austria shows similar figures to Hungary but the majority of the European coun-
tries operate with much larger local authorities. The average size in Germany is 
7400; in Poland 15,800; in the Netherlands 23,200 and in the UK where village 
authorities were attached to the towns the average local government caters for a 
population of 129,000. These high population figures are the result of the admin-
istrative contractions of the 1960s and 1970s, which were aimed at making public 
administration more efficient and economic. Today, in Europe (in the Scandina-
vian countries, in Germany, in the Benelux countries and in Great Britain, too) 
there are far less local authorities than in 1950  (Norton,  A. 1994). It is only in Hun-
gary where the situation. of 1950 was re-established. The process by which the 
number of Hungarian local authorities doubled within a single year (1990) is 


Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
unique in Europe. The Act enabled the settlements, which maintained their original 
name to elect their local body independent from their size. The newly elected local 
government of course bears the totality of local governmental rights, may set up its 
own office or establish institutions, etc.  This disintegration process runs counter 
to the European trends and is continuing nowadays: (Table 
1-2) communities still 
detach themselves from the municipalities. Due to the fragmentation, the func-
tioning of the administrative and institutional system is horrifying expensive and 
operates in many municipalities with low proficiency. The social—psychological 
explanation for the disintegration prior to independence is understandable; it is not 
only in local politics that sentiments dominate rationality  (Pcilne Kovcics, I.  1993). 
Local authorities in some instances foster these ambitions through the distribution 
and financial mechanisms and do not try to channel local administration into rea-
sonable framework by co-ordinate means. 
2.2 Weak meso-tier 
The second feature of the Hungarian model is the loss of importance of the county 
self-governance. The 1990 Act on Local Governments states that the county may 
assume only those functions, which the municipalities cannot be obliged to per-
form or refuse to assume ("subsidiarity"). The disadvantage to county assemblies 
obviously declared by the constitution from the very beginning  (Figure 1): 
If we consider first of all the elections as the general basis of local governmen-
tal legitimacy we will see the following: In course of the first elections county 
assemblies were elected indirectly by electors. Therefore they had only  secondary 
legitimacy  
deriving from the municipalities. Although the county — in this inter-
pretation — should have functioned as a representative body of local governments, 
it was exactly its relationship to local governments, which was not properly de-
fined. First of all, not all of the local governments were represented in the county 
assembly and this was particularly true for the counties with a high number of tiny 
villages. Furthermore, the law included no provisions for the direct relationship 
between county and municipalities while taking great care not to restrict the 
autonomy of the settlement in any way. 
The inferiority of the county-level is also expressed in the  division of tasks and 
responsibilities.  The county was granted tasks covering larger geographic areas or 
the whole county while the local government of any settlement may assume the 
same tasks on its own or in co-operation with other local governments. The mu-
nicipalities have the right to delegate tasks or institutions supplying larger districts 
with their arbitrary decision to the county. It means, that the  functions and compe-
tencies of the counties can change in specie and time  
and the continuous modifi- 
10 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
cations depend on the unilateral decisions of local governments, which may curtail 
or delegate the task.  
The destiny and the "owner" of the institutions with district 
tasks are therefore uncertain. 
Table 1 
Main data on local governments 1 January 1992, 1998, 2000 
Year 
Local 
Local govern- Villages bound 
District 
Notary-district seats 
governments 
ments with to notary (corn- (common) 
located in 
single offices mon) districts 
notary 
Number 
offices 
Cities Large Villages 
villages 
1992 
3092 
1439 
506 
1998 
3154 
1759 
1395 
505 
28 
35 
436 
2000 
3158 
1762 
1396 
536 
29 
36 
471 
Source:  The Register of Names of Localities of the Hungarian Republic, 1997. Budapest, Central 
Statistical Office. 
Table 2 
Number and population of settlements by population size-groups, 
1 January 1997 and 2000 
Population size groups 
Number of settlements 
Percentage distribution of the 
-
population 
1997 
2000 
1997 
2000 
— 
499 
1 009 
1  032 
2.7 
2.8 
500 — 
999 
703 
687 
5.1 
5.0 
1 000  — 
1  999 
652 
655 
9.2 
9.4 
2 000 — 
4 999 
491 
483 
14.4 
14.4 
5 000  — 
9  999 
135 
138 
9.2 
9.5 
10 000  — 49 999 
116 
115 
22.4 
22.0 
50 000  — 99  999 
11 
12 
7.0 
7.5 
100 000  — 



30.0 
29.4 
Total 
3 126 
3  131 
100.0 
100.0 
Source:  Territorial Statistical Annual, 1996. Budapest, Central Statistical Office. 
The third point is that the activities of the county-level government are "oh 
ovo" restricted by the definition of the  legal status of towns with county rank.  The 
Hungarian Parliament decided the establishment of 23 towns of county rank. The 
Act on Local Governments granted the right to the towns with county rank (i.e. all 
11 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
towns with a population of more than 50,000 or smaller if they are county seats, 
and therefore their number exceeds that of counties), to undertake county—tier 
competencies within their own geographic area. Towns with county rank do not 
have representation in the county assembly and there is no co-ordination between 
them, thus county assemblies represent only small municipalities and towns. 
Towns with county rank function parallel to the county assemblies. This parallel 
functioning complicates the administration of county-level services and the 
formulation of global developmental objectives for the entire county is fairly 
difficult and probably over dimensioned. Despite the lopsided operation of 
counties the government did not encourage the partnership. As a result of the 
division of interests within the local governmental system the measures of 
centralisation and delegation of interests could be passed practically without any 
limitations. 
Figure 1 
Map of public administration in Hungary 
Borsod-Abai,j- 
Zemplen 
• 
Salgotarjan 
Szabolcs-Szatmar- 
Miskolc 
Bereg 
Nograd 
Eger C) 
Nyiregy haza 

Gyir 
Heves 
Wpm  Gyor-
Eszter • o 
Debrecen 
Moson-Sopro  Tatab ny 
KOest 
Hajdu-Bihar 
asz-Nagykun 
Szombathely 
Sztesfehe 
Szolnok 
Veszprem 

Pest 
Vas 
Szolnok 
Veszprem 
Fejer 
• 
Ow' 
Dunaujvarros 
Keeskemit 
Zalaegerszeg 
Bakes 
Zala 
Bacs-Kiskun 
C) 
Bekescsab 
agykanizsa 
Somogy 
Tolna 
songrad 
Szekszard 
• 
Kaposvar 
Odmezdvisirhe y 
*Szeged 

Seekszird 
*pees 

Baranya 
Sopron 
• 

Key: 1
country borders, 2 — county borders, 3 — county seat, 4 — town with county raub 
— 
12 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
2.3  Expanding deconcentrated state administration 
The state, ever since it established the formal—legal autonomy of local govern-
ments in decision—making, has never given up the ambition to restrict this auton-
omy as much as possible. The division of labour between local governments and 
state organisations and the regulation of the means for implementation of local 
government tasks were mainly regulated by simple laws and governmental decrees, 
therefore the Parliament lost control and influence on the process. Although the 
government did not diminish the independence of decision—making and the organ-
isational autonomy of the local authorities, it continuously narrowed the scope of 
decision-making by taking over a significant part of local and territorial public 
affairs. The strengthening of the deconcentrated public administration took place 
mainly at the expense of the county assembly. The unhealthy degree of the Hun-
garian deconcentration can be explained in different ways. 
It is typical that central government considers centralisation as the ideal form of 
implementing tasks. Thus it is a Hungarian speciality that this centralisation ten-
dency cannot be limited either by the legal regulation of the Constitution, or by the 
channels of interests of county and local governments. Essentially, there is no 
public legal guarantee of state construction and operation progressing towards 
political decentralisation. 
Another hothead of deconcentration is the structure and model of the national 
government whereby individual branches represent a greater weight than the com-
plex interest of governments as collective bodies. A blatant example of this is that 
the ministries were provided with almost unlimited right to create their own de-
concentrated sectoral structure subordinated to their organisational interests. Al-
most all ministries made the most of this possibility. 
The disperse structure was built first on the former county council administra-
tional branches after the local elections. Therefore land, labour, public health, 
consumer and fire control administration fell under the auspices of the relevant 
ministries. The role of the former financial and planning departments of county 
councils for example was taken over by agencies subordinated to the Ministry of 
Interior and the Ministry of Finance. Offices and agencies such as the compensa-
tion offices and property transfer committees, etc. were set up to cater for tempo-
rary tasks. In the first four years following the systemic change, more than ten new 
types of deconcentrated organs were created, bringing the total number of state 
regional agency types up to almost forty, in community, county, and regional lev-
els  (Figure 2). 
As creating these organisations, the national government was not forced to con-
sider whether it was financially or professionally feasible to set up a new organi-
sation responsible for one single task. Arguments were always ready: on the basis 
13 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
Figure 2 
Central and Regional Public Administration in Hungary in 1994 
Ministries 
Their regional organs 
(in each county or region) 

Ministry of Home Affairs 

Refugee Office 

Public Administration Office 

Financial and Administrative Information Service 

Fire Service 

Ministry of Agriculture 

Veterinary Service 

Institute for Species Experiments and Dairy Products 

Plant Sanitation 

Forest Inspectory 

Land Office, Office for Agriculture 

Ministry of Defence 
Defence Replacement Headquarters 

Ministry of Justice 

Ministry of Industry and Trade 

Regional Offices of State Energy Security Supervisory Board 

Consumer Protection 

Office of Geology 

Office for Measure Calibrating 

Mining Office 

Ministry of Environmental and Regional Development 

Environmental Supervisory Office 

Directorate of Nature Conservation 

Directorate of National Parks 

Offices of Regional Chief Architect 

Ministry of Transport, Communication and Water Conservancy 

County Transport Supervisory Office 

Telecommunication Supervisory Offices 

Regional Water Management Directorates 

Public utilities, companies for road maintenance 

Ministry of Foreign Affairs 

Ministry of Culture and Education 

Ministry of Labour 

Supervisory Offices of Labour Security and Labour 

Labour Centre 

Ministry of Public Welfare 
I •  Regional Public Health Service 

Ministry of Finance 

Directorate of Public Taxation and Control 

Central Statistical Office 
I •  Directorate of Statistics 

Economic Competition Office 
Note:  In the figure, we do not show the central and regional organs of the Frontier Guards, the Police, 
penal authorities, the National Security Office (Ministry of Home Affairs) and the Customs 
Office (Ministry of Finance) as armed bodies and the organs of Ministry of Defence. 
14 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
of the legislation relating to county assemblies, there is no other way but creating a 
disperse organisation since county governments were not allowed to undertake 
tasks which might create a hierarchy in their relationship with the municipalities. 
Without going into details of the system, it is necessary to point out, that the gov-
ernment willingly decreased the competencies of the self-governments in fields 
where the nature of the task theoretically would have require an elected county 
body. Some of the newly established deconcentrated organs proved to be superflu-
ous or malfunctioning. There is a great deal of parallel functions and a lack of co-
ordination within the territorial administration while important functions remained 
in abeyance. Especially in regional development and labour market administration 
the bureaucratic and hierarchic functioning of the state and the organisational 
model were disadvantageous as compared with the local governmental model. 
These phenomena undoubtedly proved the fact that as resuming office, the gov-
ernment did not have a conscious concept of state construction or if it did it were 
unable to put it into practice. 
If we examine more carefully the method of power delegation, we will find that 
the decision-making authority shifted upwards in the hierarchy with complete dis-
regard for the local governments. 
The meso-tier integration was absent in the structure of territorial government. 
An information, development and management centre would have been required 
which is capable of flexibly representation and co-ordination of the autonomous 
actors in the economic and local governmental sphere, bearing their local and re-
gional interests in mind, but without a direct profit orientation. 
However, the government made some efforts to establish a kind of medium tier 
co-ordination unit for public administration. For this sake the government assigned 
in 1990 the so-called prefects of the republic in eight regions, which were created 
specially for this aim. Yet, the prefects of the republic had to face the general lack 
of trust and popularity, among others for the reason that they tried to practice a 
kind of prefectoral power against the local governments enjoying the "ecstasy" of 
freedom. The governmental representative (which used to be called historically 
Lord Lieutenant) with great traditions in Hungarian public administration lost its 
quasi-political character. In 1994 the position was reintegrated in the county sys-
tem where he carried out rather lawfulness control and appeal authority tasks. 
2.4 Lack of associations 
The low efficiency of the rather small municipalities of the Latin countries is bal- 
anced with the system of associations and the assistance of the medium tier. In 
Hungary in spite of the fragmentation of municipalities the associations are fairly 
15 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
rare in the local and micro-regional level. The fact that the counties lost their in-
fluence would not be so painful if the towns or settlements with central functions 
could take their role, i.e. assume the responsibility for integration within the area 
or the settlements around the town. The law provides this possibility but no means 
oblige the cities and villages to associate and in fact they did not seem to be moti-
vated at all. The former settlement development policy and service management 
practice before 1990 granted only public administrative status to functions of set-
tlements; the higher status went together with the responsibility for supplies de-
fined on a normative basis. The cities and settlements in the surrounding were in 
1984 organised in a common administrative unit, yet no real, vital contact could be 
established. Towns were not able to implement a real administrative integration 
even in the old regime and by now they have completely given up this ambition. In 
our survey in 1994 and 1998 the results showed that the settlements only associ-
ated under the pressure of necessity or in many cases not at all  (Table 3-4). 
Table 3 
Number of the settlements (districts) participating in associations (1992) 
Number of Associations for Associations 
Other 
Common body 
Settlements 
administrative 
for Services 
of 
tasks 
Provision 
Representatives 
Total 
3135 
923 
411 
77 
57 
Source:  Ministry of Interior, 1992. 
Table 4 
Number of settlements (districts) participating in associations (1999) 
Number of 
Associations for 
Number of municipalities 
settlements 
administrative tasks 
participating in an association 
Total 
3135 
1430 
2439 
Source:  Ministry of Interior, 1999. 
They rather negotiate informally with the local government providing for a 
service for them when employing the service. Similarly, the interviews revealed 
that the majority of towns failed in establishing deliberate relationships with their 
surrounding. Even if contacts were established, this happened usually not on the 
basis of the recognition of mutual interests, the co-operations are mainly motivated 
by transitional financing difficulties and cases of necessity. The tiny villages lo-
cated in urban attraction zones preferred smaller decentralised areas as their ad- 
16 

 
 
 
 
 
 
 
Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
ministrative partners. We could not discover any association, which was able to 
co-ordinate a whole urban surrounding unit. Several associations were established 
but they all focused on single issue, like a certain investment development, the 
improvement of infrastructure, or various development projects, but there seemed 
to be no need for general, comprehensive co-operation or joint planning. 
By 1994 we could find a relatively high number of voluntary established so 
called micro-regional associations. They usually set the target of developing the 
local economy and infrastructure. They will gain importance first after the Act on 
Regional Development and Physical Planning, yet we will come back to this mat-
ter later  (Table 5-6). 
Table 5 
Situation of micro-regional development associations in 1994 
Location 
Associations 
No 
Number of 
No Total number of 
data 
organisations 
data 
organisations 
With their seat in a 
having a having no 
town 
village 
city as a member 
Totally 
62,0 
58,0 
20,0 
93,0 
44,0 
3,0 
140,0 
Percentage of the total 
44,3 
41,4 
14,3 
66,4 
31,4 
2,2 
100,0 
number 
Source:  Paine Kovacs, I. 1994. 
Table 6 
Situation of micro regional development associations in 1999 
-
Totally 263 micro—regional organisations of which 
52.0% are associations of local governments without legal personality 
14.1% 
associations with legal personality 
28.0% civil organisations 
5.9% other 
Source:  G. Fekete, E. 1999. 
Yet, prior to the introduction of the Act the general aversion to planning and to 
co-operation was characteristic, but obviously the legislation on associations also 
contributed to lack of motivation to associate. The Act on Local Governments 
recognised the importance of associations and considered them as legal entities. 
But the  regulation was not elaborated in detail in order to surmount the gap be- 
17 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
tween the fragmented local decision making system and the services and infra-
structure organised by districts. 
For lack of comprehensive and clear regulations 
local governments are obviously anxious about losing their autonomy to an organi-
sation capable of taking. Therefore they fail to realise the advantages and the ne-
cessity of association. 
The rise of the disintegration process was actually not the government's respon-
sibility, rather the consequence of the weaknesses of the Act on Local Govern-
ments as well as of the political pressure behind the regulations of the act. The 
government looked on the disintegration process inactively. The handicaps result-
ing from disintegration were gradually realised. Several reform ideas were formu-
lated within the central government to reverse the than situation. The ministries of 
regional development and labour recognised and supported the integration of 
smaller regions, as mentioned above. 
Summarising,  the Act on Local Governments had tremendous importance in the 
construction of the Hungarian democratic state structure. Local communities were 
given a wide scope of competencies and autonomy and therefore they became im-
portant schools of democratic political learning. Yet, the  Act was despite its liber-
alism unable to guarantee the decentralisation of state administration and organi-
sation, thus the local self-government sector could not become a dominant element 
of territorial administration. 

Generally, the Act can be evaluated as very progressive with the remark that in 
many aspects it only outlines the frameworks of functioning not considering on the 
other hand the following circumstances: 
• In the division of functions, the border between the state and local govern-
ments should have been made more unambiguous, as a protection against the 
inevitably expanding central power. The Act on Local Governments created 
only the frameworks but did not filled them with competencies and means of 
implementation, means of the so-called simple laws and government decrees. 
• The autonomy of local governments requires not only rights but political and 
economic guarantees too, since without them the autonomy can be no more 
than formal legal fact. 
• Local societies and politicians were not yet prepared for the liberty given to 
local governments and this inevitably led to functional disturbances. The in-
stitutional system of training and retraining of the staff of local authorities 
has not been implemented to date, although this would have been highly nec-
essary because of the transformation. 
18 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
3 The regional development policy before 1996 
The contradictory structure of the medium tier, the lack of territorial self-govern-
ment not only caused disturbances in territorial administration but contributed to 
the over centralisation of the government's regional development policy. The gov-
ernment recognised the political importance of managing regional inequity, but 
• was unable to formulate a consistent regional policy; 
• did not clarify competencies within the government; and 
• represented a paternalistic regional development policy with unclear objec-
tives. 
A consistent regional development policy was also hindered by a number of 
branches interfering with local processes in a rather uncoordinated way. 
The competencies of regional development within the government were not 
clear. Regional development activity in most countries is unable to gain enough 
political weight to be undertaken by an independent ministry. In Hungary due to 
rivalry within the government this governmental activity was for decades divided 
into settlement development and regional development even though exactly these 
activities require strict co-ordination. 
Even though regional policy had an independent ministry for itself, the Ministry 
for Environment Protection and Regional Development, however, the Ministry's 
weight within the government was rather less compared to sectoral departments or 
to the Ministry of Interior supervising local authorities. 
Almost all the branches undertook settlement and regional development activi-
ties in a dual organisation system. 
• A number of ministries set up their own departments of regional develop-
ment, which launched tenders for targeted support for focal authorities. 
• The "second line" was the functioning of the county-level deconcentrated 
organisations of ministries. One type of the deconcentrated organs, the so-
called state commissioner was particularly important in terms of regional de-
velopment. The role of the state commissioner was varying in the county tier 
crisis-treatment programmes initiated by the central government. Yet, the 
common feature of the role of the prefects of the republic was, that they we 
eager to keep county assemblies far away from the decision-making. The 
government assigned different ministries with the management of the certain 
crisis counties and prefects of the republic were to organise the local imple-
mentation. Later, the prefects of the republic set up various committees and 
consultative organs (with no public legal control whatsoever) to "legitimise" 
their decisions. 
19 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
• The next stage was the establishment of the development councils with the 
participation of central and local actors once again with uncertain public le-
gal background. 
In 1993 government policy became more transparent owing to the strengthening 
significance and regulation of the Regional Development Fund. Parliament passed 
a resolution about the guidelines of regional development allocations and the eligi-
bility of assisted regions. 
The government's explicit regional development policy was formulated essen-
tially in the county programmes. The common feature of these programmes was 
that the government launched or stopped them based on its unilateral decisions. 
This method followed misdirected, paternalistic traditions. The county assemblies 
(self-governments) were excluded from the preparation and implementation of 
county programmes. 
In financing regional and settlement development the centralisation by the gov-
ernment was extreme.  The efficiency of financing regional and settlement devel-
opment was deteriorated by the dominance of targeted central support, the lack of 
co-ordination between branches and the poor ability of territorial partnerships to 
enforce interests. The efficiency of regional development policy was deteriorating 
due to the fact that the objectives of social assistance, crisis management and eco-
nomic development were entangled, therefore the utilisation of allocations was 
inefficient. 
However, this functioning remained of spending public resources rather than of 
development activities. Supporting dynamic, innovative and enterprise promoting 
centres, which would have a strong influence on their environment and contribute 
to the country's economic growth, unfortunately did not feature among the objec-
tives of regional development. Support should be granted to the poorest regions as 
an expression of solidarity and as a possible act of promoting the local economy 
instead of providing subsidies on purely social grounds. However, the chances of 
economic progress in backward areas were quite slim, at least prior to a country-
wide low economic growth. 
The government's experts apparently did not realise the new regional processes 
in Hungary (which went on for twenty years in Western Europe), which will give 
rise to a regional organisation different than in the past few decades and which will 
enforce the improvement regional policy means and objectives  (Enyedi, Gy.—Palne 
Kovacs, I.  
1994). 
Despite of all these, the perspective of development was towards a decentral-
ised and multi-sectoral model in which not only regional and local governments 
but also other public bodies, direct administrative structures, actors of business and 
civil sectors will find a place. At the same time, it was hoped that the initial proc-
esses would transform the boundaries between the profit and non-profit sector. 
20 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
4 Reform of the local governmental system in 1994 
The national government realised, earlier than local authorities, the vacuum in the 
territorial integration, which was left behind by the fall of the counties. The lack of 
a territorial integrative organisation was especially disturbing in the government's 
operation because it coincided with the disintegration of the local governmental 
structure. 
Therefore government experts proposed the reconsideration and modification 
of the Act on Local Governments. The government's programme for updating pub-
lic administration also proposed the reassessment of the deconcentrated organisa-
tional form. The experts of the Ministry of Internal Affairs reinforced the signifi-
cance of the improvement of the Act on Local Governments and proposed amend-
ments were formulated. 
During the first governmental cycle local governments (especially small mu-
nicipalities) "got" a great deal from the government. However, along with the pa-
ternalistic attention number trends evolved suggesting that this policy will be on 
the long term unsuccessful in managing regional development problems or re-
gional differences of public services. Organisational disintegration, the deteriora-
tion of the professionalism in public administration, the uniformity of infrastruc-
ture investments by local governments, unrefined administrative deconcentration, 
the unhealthy extent of central redistribution all become obstacles of the exploita-
tion of the advantages of real decentralisation which is the great potential of the 
local governmental model. 
4.1 Slow integration 
The new government elected in 1994 tried to counteract one of the most contra-
dictory processes by measures suggesting a cautious  but  evidently more up-to-date 
concept: 
• Legal prescribed requirements of the establishment of new municipalities 
became more rigorous. According to the modification settlements with less 
than 300 inhabitants may not receive the status of independent municipali-
ties. 
• additional financial benefits were promised to self-governments associating 
with each other. 
In the wake of the autonomy of small settlement local governments it was nec-
essary establish at least a basic infrastructure level (schools, city halls, water sup-
ply etc.). This admittedly brought about spectacular changes in the image of mu-
nicipal self-governments and came as a revelation to the local population. In the 
21 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
same small settlements, the "enrichment of the public sector" was coupled with 
high unemployment and the shattering of the villages' economic basis. Construc-
tion on one side, demolition on the other; and which of the trends would be lasting 
and how will they affect each other? What should be state resources used for? 
How can the local society of the settlements be convinced that autarchy and self-
contained autonomy is insufficient way surmounting the crisis? Would the gov-
ernment assist for the long-term regression, if it supports "local egoism"? Which is 
the right model for the villages: traditionalism or modernisation? 
These questions are also inherent in amendments, which allegedly aim at ad-
ministrative rationality. It was a question, what economic management and devel-
opment strategy should follow the rules suggesting conceptual change. Can the 
government undertake measures under the aegis of the "modernisation pro-
gramme", which will most probably be politically unpopular? It had a symbolic 
value that in the 1995 budget, a special contingency provides funding for associa-
tions established for the maintenance of primary school educational institutions 
and purchase of school buses instead of the former practice, individual school con-
structions. Government comments on the bankruptcy of self-governments also 
allude to previous wasteful investment decisions and admit that the resources for 
funding new institutions petered out. The modification of the grant system should 
also promote integration.  These tiny signals forecast the integrative intention 
within the self-government system, which, however, met considerable political 
opposition  
and resistance on behalf of the self-governments. 
Nevertheless, the modernisation of the local government system in the devel-
oping countries indicate, that the structural reform or the generalisation of the as-
sociative system will be inevitable sooner or later. The vacillation of the govern-
ment in other issues may bear the way of a more progressive regional and local 
development strategy when it comes to taking politically unpopular steps. The 
central government could motivate the association of municipalities first of all by 
financial regulation because the most important part of the local budget is coming 
from the central state despite that the proportion of local revenues increased within 
the local budgets  (Table 7). 
The measures for the enhancement of the economy of scale considered as the 
administrative precondition of modernisation do not seem to be very successful 
from the perspective of ten years. Notwithstanding the parliament passed an inde-
pendent act on the associations of local governments, but this new act was unable 
to motivate the settlements to co-operation. There were certain modifications in 
the financing too, which actually favoured associations in the course of the distri-
bution of supports. The differentiated division of labour is encouraged by the 
trend, that currently larger local governments, especially those nearby the cities are 
assigned with district scale supply tasks. However as a whole the local govern- 
22 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
mental provision of tasks is still fragmented. Unfortunately no comprehensive 
survey was carried out on this topic either. The conclusion declared currently by 
the Hungarian Audit Office based on a representative survey is fairly characteris-
tic: there is no information on the impacts of the decision-making competency 
related to the implementation of the 3646 local governmental tasks and competen-
cies. The above survey (with some 20% representation) proves that the proportion 
of the associations in the organisation of public services was only 6,9% in 1999 
(Hungarian Audit Office,  2000). 
Table 7 
Local government budgets as % of total incomes between 1993-1997 
Incomes 
1993 
1994 
1995 
1996 
1997 
1999 
Beneficial income total 
17.6 
14.3 
16.0 
19.4 
19.3 
28.8 
From the foregoing: 
Duties 
1.7 
1.2 
1.5 
1.4 
1.3 
Local taxes 
4.5 
4.1 
3.9 
7.7 
8.0 
12.9 
surrendered income total 
8.5 
9.6 
13.0 
11.5 
13.8 
13.3 
From the foregoing: 
Personal income tax 
8.1 
9.2 
12.6 
10.7 
13.0 
12.4 
Car tax 
0.4 
0.4 
0.4 
0.7 
0.8 
0.7 
own and surrendered incomes totally 
26.1 
23.9 
29.1 
30.9 
33.1 
42.1 
Accumulation and capital income totally 
8.1 
10.0 
9.4 
9.7 
8.6 
8.3 
State grants and subsidies total 
42.6 
44.3 
41.3 
35.6 
34.7 
29.1 
From the foregoing: 
Normative state grants 
35.6 
33.2 
31.3 
24.6 
24.6 
18.7 
Designated and targeted subsidies 
3.0 
5.0 
4.5 
3.2 
3.7 
2.5 
Personal income tax contribution 
1.1 
1.0 
Social Security funds 
15.2 
11.5 
13.3 
16.0 
16.2 
13.7 
Other funds, repayments, bond repayment 
3.8 
1.7 
2.8 
3.9 
3.4 
4.0 
Credit, bond incomes 
4.2 
8.6 
4.0 
3.9 
4.0 
2.8 
Annual income total 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
Source:  Financial Review  1995. 1., 1997. 1.,  2000. 9. 
4.2 Ambivalent strengthening of county assemblies 
One of the most important changes in the local government system was the intro-
duction of the direct election system at the county level in order to  strengthen the 
legitimacy of county government  in 1994. The system of elections did not prove to 
be successful. At the same time the establishment of two artificial "constituencies" 
per county for the settlements with more or less than 10,000 inhabitants respec- 
23 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
tively appeared to solve or rather circumvented the problem of area delimitation 
within the county. These categories had nothing to do with interests within the 
county as they separated the town from its surrounding. This election system was 
definitely in contradiction with the intention of the government programme and 
left the representative proportions within the county assembly to sheer chance. In 
the course of the elaboration of the election technique the basic concept whereby 
the government recognises micro-regional associations within the counties and 
intends to rely on them in regional policy was completely forgotten.  As a result of 
the unique election technique party politicians are in majority in the county as-
semblies,  
who can hardly satisfy their political ambitions having only restricted 
competencies and space of movement.  It was a big mistake to create bodies with 
strong political legitimacy for the restrictedly increased number of competency 
and power. 

A positive legal dogmatic step was providing counties the status of "territorial 
government", as a result of which the concept of division of competencies between 
the municipal and county level could have been reassessed. Unfortunately in spite 
of that, county governments did not receive an adequate amount of competencies 
and tasks even after modifying the election system and reinforcing their status, 
since both the municipalities and the ministries resisted during the reforms in 1994 
granting the counties more significant competencies. 
Another sign of rationalisation was that the chairman and the chief administra-
tor of the county assembly could be vested with sate administrative authority. Ac-
cording to the former legal dogmatic concept, county governments could not as-
sume duties, which might create a hierarchy over local self-governments. The for-
mer four years this rigid rule or principle was the pretext for the establishment of 
deconcentrated offices, i.e. the nationalisation of a significant part of territorial 
duties. The government's objective to streamline and rationalise territorial level 
state administration could, in this way, be realised even if state administrative 
tasks are delegated to the competence of the county self-governments. 
4.3 Careful steps towards the integration of territorial state 
administration 
As already mentioned, directly after the new government assumed office and 
following the large political debate on the "prefects" symbolising the centralised 
state, the eight administrative regions of the prefects of the Republic were 
abolished. With this step the new government practically renounced the ambition 
of direct interference into local and territorial matters  (Pcilne Kovcics, I.  1995). 
24 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
In 1996 the government announced a comprehensive program on the reform of 
public administration. The objective of the program was to rationalise and 
integrate the fragmented public administrative system in the territorial tier and to 
establish co-ordination through the offices of county assemblies replacing the 
former "prefects". Four years after the announcement of the state administrative 
reforms we ought to admit that they were only partially successful. It is undeniable 
that the number of independent deconcentrated organs decreased, preliminary due 
to the integration of the territorial units under the supervision of the same ministry. 
Yet, county assemblies have only weak co-ordination means and more important 
tasks were not delegated (back) from the deconcentrated sector to the county 
assemblies.  Therefore, the dominance of the state/deconcentrated sector in the 
territorial tier remained unchanged (Figure 3). 

5 The act on regional development in 1996 
5.1 The regulation 
As regards regional power, besides the Act on Local Governments and the reforms 
of the state administrative system the most important and possibly most ambiguous 
step was the enactment of the Act on Regional Development and Physical Plan-
ning in 1996. The most important objectives the integration of the different 
branches in the economic and regional policy; the harmonisation of the environ-
mental, labour market, infrastructure, housing and regional policies; and focus on 
the local resources and needs. These trends involved the necessity of the decen-
tralisation of public administration and a more flexible management of regional 
policy establishing partnerships with the actors of the social and private sectors. 
The failures of the former regional policy were caused by the centralised adminis-
trative system neglecting the local actors in the regional development decision-
making. Recognising this mistake the government undertook decentralisation. 
The different political and professional forums raised various requirements to-
wards the slowly shaping act, which were finally included to the dominant princi-
ples of the act: 
• The government intended to create the foundations of one single regional 
policy operating under common rules, having a concept and covering the en-
tire country —  the principle of programming. 
• The advanced regions — in the name of efficiency — expected to be granted 
supplementary support for their further development —  the principle of inno-
vation and additionality. 

25 

 
 
Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
Figure 3 
Central and Regional Public Administration in Hungary in 1998 
Ministries 
Their regional organs 
(in each county or region) 

Prime Minister's Office 

Ministry of Home Affairs 

County and Capital City Public Administrative Offices (20) 

(Consumer Protection Inspectorates, Public Guardianship Offices, 
Property Transfer Committees) 

Refugee and Migration Office 

Territorial State Household and Administrative Information Services (19) 

County and Local Fire Service 

County and Capital City Civil Defence Headquarters 

Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development 

Headquarters of Veterinary and Food Inspection Services (20) 

Territorial branches of National Compensation Bureau (13) 

Stations for Plant Improvement and Soil protection (20) 

State Forestry Services (10) 

County and Capital City Land Registry Offices (20) 

Offices of Agrarian Affairs (19) 

Stations for Species Experiments (28+8) 
Ministry of Defence 

Ministry of Justice 

Ministry of Economy 

Regional Offices of Technical Security Inspectorate (10) 

Territorial Offices of Geology (7) 

Offices for Measure Calibrating (20) 

Mining Office (4) 

Regional Secretariats of Tourism Committees (9) 

by the parts of the ministry 

Ministry of Environmental Protection 

Environmental Supervisory Offices (12) 

Directorates of National Parks (9) 

Offices of Regional Chief Architect byparts of the ministry 

Ministry of Transport, Communication and Water Conservancy 

County Transport Supervisory Office (12) 

Telecommunication Supervisory Offices (5) 

Regional Water Management Directorates (12) 

Ministry of Foreign Affairs 

Ministry of Culture and Education 

Ministry of the National Cultural Heritage 

Ministry of Youth and Sport 

Ministry of Social and Family Affairs 

County and Capital City Labour Offices (20) 

Ministry of Public Health 
I   Regional 
 • 
 Public Health Service (20) 

Ministry of Finance 
I • Directorate of Public Taxation and Control (20) 

Central Statistical Office 

Territorial Directorates (20) 
Source:  Verebely I., 1998. pp. 420-421. 
26 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
• The crisis regions expected the government to focus on their development —
the principle of concentration. 
• The local governments of the small and tiny settlements were hoping to re-
main the beneficiaries of different grants —  the principle of solidarity. 
• Economic actors wanted to participate in the shaping and financing of devel-
opment policy as equal partners —  the principle of partnership. 
• County governments required under the slogan of decentralisation the en-
largement of their competencies and resources —  the principle of subsidiarity 
and decentralisation. 
The county assemblies were already disappointed as the act was passed. They 
in vain expected the Act on Regional Development and Physical Planning to ar-
range what only a norm of general political value, the Constitution and the Act on 
Local Governments could have arranged. Namely, they wished to receive a. role in 
regional policy and to be integrated as real territorial bodies into the system of 
power. Their hopes were cherished by the fact that the European Chart of Regional 
Governments was already shaping at that time as well as the Declaration of the 
Assembly of European Regions. These documents predicted the European trend of 
strengthening of the medium tier administration. The still existing uncertainty 
about the decentralisation of power and the lack of trust towards county assemblies 
left their mark on the regulation of regional policy, as well. 
Although the government realised the advantages of decentralisation it re-
mained reluctant to share its competencies in regional policy with the directly 
elected county government. The legislator made efforts to eliminate the contradic-
tion by introducing a special institution: the regional development councils — at 
four levels of regional policy systems  (Figure 4). 
These partnership institutions and special agencies well known in Western 
Europe were established to integrate the regional development efforts of the local 
governments, state administration, economic and civil actors  (Horvath, Gy.  1998). 
In some cases, they are even capable of working out common development pro-
grammes and to accumulate resources for the implementation of the programmes 
(Halkier, H.  et al. 1998). However, they are unable to do one thing: to substitute 
territorial self-governments bearing political legitimacy and standing on the foun-
dation of the principle of representation  (Jones, M.  1998). During the establish-
ment of the partnership institutions the "legitimacy danger" in connection with 
corporate organisations and the agencies and the weaknesses of the lacking trans-
parency were not realised yet even though the literature regularly elaborates the 
topic  (Thynne, 1.  2000). In Hungary the motivation was to avoid/ignore the elected 
county assembly by creating the territorial development councils, the principle of 
partnership was rather an excuse than target. 
27 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
SETTLEMENT I MICRO- 
I COUNTY I REGIONAL 
I  NATIONAL 
REGIONAL 
Financial institutions, banks,  companies etc. at every level 

a. 
er 



.0 
Th

RJ  
e k
4- 

g g 
a. 
e
0  


- 1 -•  p"'" 
or
a I 
- 1 -• 
-• 
4— 
4— 

$

gi

gani
1 -• 


3  P.:  + 1 
g. 
Q. 
a. 



sati

ons 



of 
Iz 
r
e
gi

g. 

on

al 
 d
evel

o
pment i


 

n H
S g 
g 

-NO
" 6 
un
lia
gar




2,g  
luo
r  

3s 
110] 3
Organisations of civil society 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
In terms of public law it is difficult to define the nature of the territorial devel-
opment councils since the legislator did not care to describe the precise type of 
organisations to be established under the name development council. This led to 
several practical problems in their operation i.e. in their financing, employment 
matters or legal control. It was for instance not clear whether the employees of 
these organisations are civil servants. Also, while the council enjoyed great free-
dom in the facilitation of its own organisation, decision—making and resource dis-
tribution, no superior organisational control was established. 
The composition of the development council shows tripartite or corporate char-
acter, it is varying in the different tiers (like national, regional, county and micro-
regional). County development councils for example, consist of one representative 
of the county assembly, one of the cities with county rank, representatives of mi-
cro-regional associations within the county (their number is fixed by law), repre-
sentatives of employers (chambers) and the employees (trade unions) and finally 
the representative of the ministry responsible for regional policy. The composition 
of the councils was more or less suitable to co-operate the activities of the con-
cerned actors based on the principle of partnership. However the basic contradic-
tion of the model is that these development councils were equipped with far more 
power and competencies than the directly elected county assemblies. County de-
velopment councils decide upon the development concept of the county and are 
entitled to distribute state subsidies within an application system. At this place we 
have to remark, that partnership corporations or the quasi non-governmental or-
gans (quangos) are expanding not only in regional policy but also in other 
branches (such as the management of tourism, education or water). There could 
even be a welcomed tendency if evaluated from the aspect that administration is 
becoming more flexible. Still we cannot disregard the political fact, that the central 
government is often led by the ambition to bypass the county assemblies. Further, 
the increase of the "quasi", organs with an unstable status and less political legiti-
macy also harm the principle of transparency, makes co-ordination difficult and 
results in a deficit of democracy. The expansion of organisations with different 
status in the territorial tier represents fairly well the confusion in the territorial tier 
of Hungarian public administration. Deconcentrated organs, partnership organisa-
tions and other quango organisations replaced the weak self—governments. 
In spite of announcing the requirements of EU compatibility in order to inte-
grate Hungarian territorial division into the NUTS system the Act was unable to 
launch and amplify the establishment of regions larger than counties.  The act made 
the counties the dominant units of regional development and  
although it provided a 
possibility for the creation of regions larger than them it only made this compul-
sory in two regions, in the agglomeration of the capital city, Budapest and in the 
Lake Balhton region. The fundamental reason for the hesitation about the regions 
29 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
was the fact that in regionalisation not only political-power issues but also possible 
geographical borders are uncertain. The National Regional Development Concept 
of Hungary was passed by the Parliament at the spring of 1998. This document 
defined the number and borders of the NUTS 2 regions. However, the develop-
ment councils established by the Act on Regional Development were not forced to 
be organised based on the NUTS 2 regions. These councils did not receive re-
sources or competencies exactly due to the voluntary principle. The county devel-
opment councils still have the right to decide upon the geographic "region" they 
want to establish a common regional development council and further the compe-
tencies and tasks they want to endow them  (Figure 5). 
5.2 The first experiences of functioning of the regional policy 
The enactment of the Act resulted in fairly significant changes as regards the ac-
tors of territorial administration. However the new system has been functioning 
only for a few years now. The balance of the first experiences contained both, 
positive and negative phenomena. 
Strengths 
• There was a special institutional network and some decentralised fund for 
regional development. 
• A fairly positive phenomenon was that public and private actors of regional 
policy are motivated to co-operate with each other. 
• The system encouraged partnerships between rural settlements and urban 
centres in the framework of micro-regional associations. 
• The central government had to communicate with the territorial actors in 
planning and in the redistribution of resources. 
• The public sector, particularly local governments had to begin to plan their 
activities due to the Act on Regional Development and Physical Planning 
obliging them to prepare regional development plans. 
• The attitude of the local and actors and branches (ministries) was changing, 
spatial aspects are becoming more important elements in the development 
decisions. 
• The partial decentralisation of development recourses increased the effi-
ciency of regional policy. 
30 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
c,) 
 
ary 

 Hung
 in 

ions 
 reg
 t
he 

 of 
t
ions 
na
ig

 
des

r
ious 

Va

Co) 
.C) 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
Weakness 
• No territorial information system has been established yet for the creation of 
development plans and the evaluation of the implementation. 
• Skills and experts were insufficient in territorial planning. 
• There was a huge scarcity of recourses for regional policy not only due to the 
economic situation but also to the fact that ministerial departments have 
more power and the resources than the actors of regional policy. 
• Large regions were the weakest among the territorial planning units due to 
the uncertainty of geographical boundaries, willingness of county develop-
ment councils to co-operate with each other is quite low and the there is still 
a lack of own competencies, means and recourses. 
• The local actors were more motivated by short-term targets and equity than 
the requirement of efficiency and modernisation, and therefore the danger is 
real that resources will be fragmented. 
6 The agenda of the territorial reforms 
Summarising: notwithstanding the Act on Regional Development launched signifi-
cant integration processes, the problem of territorial power division has not yet 
been solved since the systemic change. The meso-level is 'floating" and neither 

professional nor political answers can be given to the following questions: 
• Do we really want to decentralise power in this country where centralisation 
has strong and long traditions? 
• What tasks shall the missing medium tier overtake? 
• How many territorial tiers are at all necessary in Hungary? 
• Which are the geographic borders of the new territorial division? 
A characteristic feature of the debate over the counties in the past decade is that 
it often appears as a merely spatial division issue hiding the real political and 
power correlation. The "anti-county group" stopped arguing that municipalities are 
able to provide all local functions thus the medium level is unnecessary. They 
argue now that the millennium-old counties are not capable any more of carrying 
out medium level tasks. The notions differ when it comes to the question whether 
they are  too small or too large.  The answer evidently depends on what tasks we 
want to render to the medium level. The county-debate sometimes votes for large 
regions other times for urban attraction zones, usually neglecting or concealing the 
political consequences. 
32 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
6.1 Reform alternatives for territorial division to replace the 
"too small" or "too large" counties 
The "city-county" (micro-regional) alternative.  Following the systemic change the 
independence of the settlements became the ultimate political interest, the greatest 
achievement of system of local governments. Naturally, the favouring of inde-
pendence of the settlements, the »l'art pour l'art« freedom could not stand long 
against proficiency and efficiency. It was soon realised that the system fragmented 
into 3200 autonomous decision-making bodies is struggling with malfunctions. 
The point of the model proposing the so-called town-counties against the counties 
is that the municipalities will be able to carry out their administrative and service 
functions in co-operation with the towns. The notion of the towns co-operating 
with their environs is of course not new either in the literature or in the history of 
Hungarian public administration. The popular political scientist of Hungary, Istvan 
Bibo, and Ferenc Erdei researching already in the period between the two World 
Wars elaborated in 1947 a concept on replacing the counties by the so called 
town—counties. The popularity of the programme published under the aegis of the 
National Peasant Party was not so much due to the rearrangement of the territorial 
system but rather to the fact, that this model was the only competitive alternative 
to the soviet model of the Communist Party. The so-called districts have existed 
for centuries in the Hungarian territorial public administration. Their scope was 
fairly similar to the proposed town-counties but the districts — with the exception 
of a short period between 1954-1971 — never had representative content, thus they 
have never been self-governments either but the administrative units of the coun-
ties. In 1984 the system of so-called urban zones was introduced to replace the 
districts but these units have never had a wide range of functions and representa-
tion. Public administration building on urban attraction zones responses to the 
need of providing services for the population and manage administrative affairs of 
the citizens in the geographical vicinity. These tasks appear in the urban attraction 
zone in close correlation. The close twinning of towns and their neighbourhood in 
the servicing and infrastructure does not necessarily require an independent public 
administrative tier. The more flexible associations of the concerned local govern-
ments are rather suitable to implement and co-ordinate common tasks. In my 
opinion,  the urban attraction zones are not alternatives but complements to the 
counties.  
The geographical scale appears lately more often in the local govern-
mental performance of tasks. Under the supervision of the government district 
offices were set up within the appointed urban local governments, which are 
authorised to issue different licences and certificates. The so-called micro-regional 
associations proved to be especially viable, which integrate the development ac-
tivities of the local governments. Encouraged by these experiences the issue of 
33 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
institutionalising the micro—regions as public administrative units was raised 
again. 
Regions above or instead of the counties.  From the historical review it is clear 
that regional (a region here means a unit larger than the county) divisions have no 
traditions in Hungary. When any attempt appeared to introduce a regional division 
different from the counties  the motivation was always centralisation,  to break 
down the national independence opposition and to empty the political content of 
the county frames. It is also obvious that none of the regionalisation attempts 
proved to be successful, the counties repelled all attacks. Despite the region is not 
an unknown category of public law since organisations with regional competencies 
have been operating for a long time in the different sectors of public administration 
(such as in the field of environment protection, water and mining management). 
Behind the debates over the counties in the recent years we can feel the distrust of 
the government and its reluctance to enable the counties to become strong politi-
cal-power counter-poles. In some cases there is nothing more behind the "Europe 
of the Regions" slogan but the mere rejection of the counties or any power unit 
between the top and the bottom. Until 1999, the modification of Act on Regional 
Development  there was quite a huge confusion concerning the number and de-
limitation of the regions.  Naturally,  without the authority and political content for 
regions it cannot be decided how many levels are necessary and whether regions 
should be organised above or instead of the counties (Pcilne Kovcics, 1.  
1997). And 
naturally without having clarified the content it is not possible to debate reasona-
bly on the geographical borders. 
6.2  The failure of the  reform debates — Concealment of political 
aspects 
The parties and professionals have been struggling with the concept of power divi-
sion at the territorial tier,  yet  a full consensus seems to be very hard to achieve. 
The future of the counties, more exactly the medium tier is now subject to signifi-
cant debates. Although these debates seem to be about whether counties, town-
counties, (micro—regions) or regions are the territorial division of the future, the 
matter is far more complex: the question is,  whether a decentralised or a central-
ised state structure should or must be created in Hungary intending to join the EU. 
The idea of federalism does not even occur to the bravest reformers, which is un-
derstandable as the spatial structure, ethnic composition and size of Hungary does 
not require a federal arrangement, yet the necessity of the medium—tier is not dis-
puted any more. Everyone seems to agree with the purpose of decentralisation, as 
it would not be elegant for the central power to narrow-mindedly stick to its 
34 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
power. The Hungarian answer is undoubtedly urged by the process, according to 
which in the neighbouring countries the regional reforms gathered a momentum 
after a long hesitation  (Regulski, J.  1998). Despite of the superficial affirmation of 
decentralisation, if examined deeper those concerned, we will find that the  coun-
ter-interested are in majority against those for decentralisation: 

• We cannot expect any politician in the central government (and especially 
not in the sectoral departments) to support with belief the restriction of their 
own power by a regional level on which of course they would have rather 
less influence on. 
• The municipalities who just tasted freedom are very distrustful with any new 
tier "above" them, even if this would function as their self-governmental 
body. 
• The most of the citizens do not understand why further bureaucratic tier 
spending their taxes is necessary. 
• The technocrats of public administration might accept that regional admini-
stration and co-ordination are necessary but they are definitely reluctant to 
let the non-professional representatives of a democratically elected political 
body interfere in "professional" issues. 
It is not at all easy to achieve real decentralisation, when the freedom of settle-
ments, which they already enjoyed is cut, but based on the experience of ten years 
we have to accept that the freedom of settlements is not able to guarantee in itself 
the decentralisation of the system.  
The Hungarian Act on Local Governments, 
which are very liberal in public political sense were not able to guarantee the spa-
tial decentralisation of power. With a bit of cynicism we can say that the govern-
ment, supporting the demand of the settlements for autonomy and autarchy, applied 
the principle of "divide et impera" as the (often counter) interests of the 3200 set-
tlements can be easily tackled without a spatial integration linking the settlements. 
Still, the strengthening of the territorial political—local governmental tier proceeded 
not only in the interest of the settlements but also of the central government, as: 
• the central decision-making is not able to receive sufficient information 
without regional partners; 
• the bureaucratic and centralising state administration is not able to get social 
support or legitimacy for its decisions; 
• the centralised and bureaucratic, uniform decision-making system is unable 
to mobilise local resources for the national priorities; 
• a more elaborate decision structure is more flexible and better at adapting to 
the changing requirements; 
• the centralised system has significantly weaker connections to the society 
and is less democratic which in turn jeopardises its legitimacy. 
35 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
These arguments, however, are too technocratic to be satisfactory for settling 
the debate over the counties, or regions eliminating the centralising reflexes and 
weakening distrust and prejudices. 
Summarising, we can say that the conceptual steps of the governments were fa-
vourable from the aspect of modernisation, rationalisation, democratic structure, 
increasing political weight and real decentralisation of power. By the comprehen-
sive amendment and reform of the self-government and of the territorial adminis-
trative system and the legislation of regional policy, the Hungarian state-develop-
ment process was pushed towards decentralisation. This will, in the longer term, 
provide self-governments with more favourable conditions and larger space of 
movement than the former paternalistic and centralising government policy. At the 
same time, specific techniques, actual measures of the governments were not al-
ways unambiguous; political compromises and branch aspirations inserted sources 
of danger in the operation, which can deteriorate the chances of implementation of 
the original ideas. The efficiency of the new order of regional policy, the advan-
tages of decentralisation of planning and decisions making on regional develop-
ment are connected with the general trends of public administration and govern-
mental policy. We can say that the chance of successful regional policy depends on 
the success of Hungarian decentralisation process and economic development 
7 The story since 1998 — the regionalisation — ultimate 
chance? 
New government — old dilemmas 
The new government proclaimed by 1998 a more resolute regionalisation. Ac-
cording to the government programme the possibility of the introduction of re-
gional public administration shall be examined by the year 2000. The government 
submitted the proposal for the modification of the Act on Regional Development 
and Physical Planning to the Parliament. According to this it is compulsory to es-
tablish regional development councils for the territory of the NUTS 2 regions. The 
aim is to create regions, which meet the regional assistance requirements of the  EU 
and will become the strongest level in the regional policy. 
The balance of the modification of the Act on Regional Development is not ex-
plicitly positive from the aspect of the requirements of EU accession. The govern-
ment, parallel to increasing the space of the regional tier development policy, ex-
panded its own power. The modification of the act violated even two of the princi-
ples of the European Union: the decentralisation (subsidiarity) and the partnership. 
36 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
Namely, the government modified the composition of the development coun-
cils: interestingly the labour councils, as the representatives of the employees and 
the economic chambers, as the representatives of the employers did not receive 
representation in the councils. Also, the representation of the micro—regions func-
tioning as the associations of municipalities was decreased. Notwithstanding it was 
a positive development that finally the mayors of the county seats are members in 
the councils, but the changes led to the situation that the representatives of the 
government acquired the majority within the councils, since in the regional tier 10 
ministries receive representation in the council. The regional and the county de-
velopment councils are not any more decentralised only deconcentrated organs if 
their composition is considered, even if they maintained some of their local repre-
sentative character. These changes worn us that the uncertain and intermediate 
status organs, as the beneficiaries or rather the subjects of decentralisation would 
hardly mean a safe constitutional solution, since they lacking the constitutional 
value and guaranties of self-governance may fall victim any time to the centralisa-
tion ambitions of the central government. 
We may come to a similar conclusion if we consider the public administration—
organisation measures of the central government. The government undoubtedly 
announced its regionalisation programme within its public administrative pro-
gramme. There are investigations carried out to identify the fields of the decon-
centrated administration, where regional integration would be possible which is if 
possible within the frameworks of the statistical regions. Therefore the adminis-
trative and other public servicing organisations were ab ovo equipped with re-
gional competency. Yet the question is,  whether the process of regionalisation will 
continue towards public administrative or political regions? 

In the present state of the debates it is difficult to forecast the future since re-
gionalisation seems to lack both sufficient professional arguments and a unified 
political will. Notwithstanding we are professionally not prepared for a total re-
gional revision and reform, still in recent times demanding regionalisation is be-
coming rather a fashion in the groves of politics. The opposition parties argue be-
sides the EU accession that if the regional tier will be the key element in regional 
development regional decision-making must be democratised as well. They justly 
refer to the fact, that the regional tier serves alongside the recent governmental 
intentions exclusively centralisation targets. 
The danger of inpatient regionalisation is not only in the lack of professional 
basis. A further, fairly important factor is that the regional identity is also absent. 
This latter is especially important, of course, if regions are organised as political 
units functioning on the principle of representation. It was in vain to emphasise the 
necessity of regionalisation and to establish regions within the state administration 
and regional development,  if the population cannot identify emotionally or cogni- 
37 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
tively with these arbitrary units.  Even their name deliver basis for debates, and 
their seats has not been clarified either. The government namely, as delimitation 
the regions and made the establishment of development councils compulsory did 
not make a decision on the seats of the regions. Ever since, there is a savage fight 
between the potential regional seats for acquiring the regional functions, institu-
tions and organisations. 
Summarising we can declare that behind regionalism, the magic notion of the 
political elite there is no conscious region building strategy. In order to elaborate 
this strategy the following matters must be clarified. 
1. The functions requiring regions larger than the counties must be identified 
and defined. No systematic investigations were carried out in this respect, which 
based on the aspects of the economy of scale could have clarified the fields of the 
current system of public administrative tasks, which would require or at least is 
able to adapt the regional scale. For the time being certain programmes and tasks 
of regional development require regional scale, we can also consider the possibil-
ity of regionalising environmental protection and tourism. In the fields of public 
health, higher education or public administration there are some functions, which 
can be regionalised, but as a whole they do not fortify yet the necessity of the es-
tablishment of a separate administrative tier. 
2. After the clarification of the functions we must define, whether these func-
tions require a new regional level with general authority, whether this  tier should 
be facilitated instead of or above the counties  
and whether smaller regional units 
below the counties shall be created. In order to be able to decide upon these ques-
tions the territorial aspect of service systems, infrastructure, accessibility must be 
analysed. Accordingly, at the time being, it is not obvious that micro-regions, the 
158 statistical urban attraction zones necessarily have to be the "lower meso—tier", 
since the spatial organisation of the district scale services and administrative ac-
tivities shows many different varieties. Their number is rather higher than 158, 
which obviously implies that the establishment of micro—regions would not mean 
an appropriate solution for the integration of regional administration, it could only 
provide for the voluntary framework of the municipal co-operation. It is especially 
important to consider whether in Hungary  two medium tiers are necessary at all. 
The Western European experiences imply that usually the smaller countries like 
Hungary content themselves with one medium tier. 
3. After having identified the number of functions and levels  the legal status of 
the region can be modelled: 
• state administrative units with an administrative office controlled by the gove 
• rnment, 
38 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
• special delegated organs with co-ordinating authority, 
• associations of local and county governments, 
• a kind of corporation, similar to the county and regional development coun-
cils 
• a directly elected self government with strong authority, or 
• a "member state" within a federalised structure. 
It is easily imaginable that in a classic unitarian country lacking regional tradi-
tions the fully authorised self—governmental status shall be achieved gradually. 
The example of Great—Britain shows, that filling up the standard regions with po-
litical—democratic content is also possible through special "preparatory" forms 
(Harding, A. et al. 1999). 
4. Having identified the content and the number of the levels, the geographical 
alternatives can be worked out. In this respect the appointment of regional centres 
is especially important. The enforcement of geographic rationality does not prom-
ise to be an easy task. The Hungarian space is differentiated by the settlement 
structure. It is almost impossible to build proportional regions on the settlements 
with the regional centre located in the geographic middle. Therefore it is important 
to build the administration on the real order of the regional spatial relationships, 
and it is also worthy to consider to establish regions with possibly different status _ 
(several examples of which exist in Europe). 
5. Subsequent to the scientific elaboration of reform alternatives, a public con-
sensus must be achieved for the decision, as I am convinced, the regional division 
of the power cannot be an internal affair of either the narrow professional sphere 
or the government. For this reason the  gradual introduction and the conscious 
nourishment of regional identity are especially important. 
As these tasks forecast implementation will take time. A hastily made, badly 
prepared and forced regionalisation may have the same fate as the former reforms, 
in addition, it would endanger the stability of the power of the governments strug-
gling with a host of social and economic problems. 
However,  until the accomplishment of the process of regionalisation in Hun-
gary counties will remain the regions,  since counties are the only units in Hungary 
that meet — yet partially — the requirements of the European Charter of Regional 
Governments. 
* * * 
In Hungary the most essential issue is not whether the counties or regions 
should make the sub-national level. The primary task is to get rid of the traditions 
of state centralisation and formulate a political will for the decentralisation of the 
power. 
39 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
References 
Dobos, L.-ne—Szelenyi, Gy. 2000: Gleaning among the results of the annual accounts of 
local governments in 1999. —  Financial Review.  9. pp. 775-802. 
Enyedi, Gy.—Palne Kovacs, I. 1994: The Government and the Local Authorities. — Gombar, 
Cs.—Hankiss, E.—Lengyel, L.—Varnai Gy. (eds):  Balance. The Hungarian Government 
1990-1994.  Budapest. Korridor, pp. 234-251. 
Enyedi, Gy.—Palne Kovacs, I. 1994: The rebirth of local government in Hungary. — Bennett, 
R. J. (ed.):  Local Government and Market Decentralization.  Tokyo, United Nation Uni-
versity Press, pp. 76-92. 
G. Fekete E. (ed.) 1999:  Kistersegi fejleszto szervezetek Magyarorszcigon az tij evezred 
kiiszoben. (Micro—regional development organisations in Hungary at the turn of the 
new century).  
Pecs, Centre for Regional Studies (Manuscript.). 
Hajdu, Z.— Paine Kovacs, I. 1994: Hungarian local government: a permanent reform? — 
Hajdu, Z.—Horvath, Gy. (eds.):  European Challenges and Hungarian Responses in Re-
gional Policy.  Pecs, Centre for Regional Studies, pp. 349-359. 
Halkier, H.—Danson, M.—Damborg, C. (eds.) 1998:  Regional development Agencies in 
Europe.  London, Jessica Kingsley. 
Harding, A.—Wilks-Heeg, S.—Hutchins, M.: Regional development agencies and English re- 
gionalisation: the question os accountability. —  Government and Policy.  6.  pp. 685-701. 
Horvath, Gy. 1998:  Regional and Cohesion Policy in Hungary.  Pecs, Centre for Regional - 
Studies. (Discussion Papers, 23.) 
Horvath, Gy. 1998:  Regional and Cohesion Policy in Hungary.  Pecs. Centre for Regional 
Studies. (Discussion Papers, 23.). 
Jones, M. 1999: New Institutional Spaces. Jessica Kingsley — Regional Studies Association, 
London. 
Kalmanne Csan, Zs.—Kovacs,  A.  1995: A helyi onkormanyzatok 1995. evi koltsegvetesi 
kapcsolatainak jellemzoi (Features of budgetary relationships of local governments in 
1995). —  Penziigyi Szemle.  1. pp. 1-20. 
Norton, A. 1994: International Handbook of Local and Regional Government. Edward 
Elgar, Aldershot. 
Paine Kovacs, I. (ed.) 1994:  Kistersegek, megyek, regiok es a kozeljiivo kOzigazgatcisa 
(Micro-regions, countries, regions and the public administration of the near future). 
Pecs, Centre for Regional Studies (Manuscript.). 
Paine Kovacs, I. 1993:  The Basic Political and Structural Problems in the Working of Lo- 
cal Governments in Hungary.  Pecs, Centre for Regional Studies. (Discussion Papers, 14.). 
Paine Kovacs, I. 1995: The Government's Gestures and Strictures in the Process of Decen-
tralisation. — Gombar, Cs.—Hankiss, E.—Lengyel, L. —Varnai, Gy. (eds.):  Question 
Marks: The Hungarian Government 1994-1995.  Budapest, Korridor. 
Paine Kovacs, I. 1997: The role of local governments in the process of state decentralisa-
tion in Hungary. — T. Log—Nowak, D. Armstrong. (eds.):  Emerging Conceptions of De-
mocracy in Transition Europe.  
International Symposium Materials University of 
40 

Pálné Kovács, Ilona: Regional Development and Governance in Hungary. 
Pécs: Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 41 p. 
Discussion Papers, No. 35.
Wroclaw and International Centre at Thbingen. Wroclaw, Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu 
Wroclawskiego, pp. 187-204. 
Regulski, J. 1998:  Building Democracy in Poland.  Budapest, Open Society Institute. 
Stewart, J.—Stoker, G. (eds.) 1995:  Local government in the 1990s.  London, MacMillan 
Thynne, I. 2000: The state and the governance: issues and challenges in perspective —  Inter- 
national review of Administrative Science.  June, pp. 227-241. 
Varga, S. 1997: Mivel szamolhatnak a helyi onkormanyzatok? (What can local governments 
expect?). — Penziigyi Szemle.  1. pp. 29-31. 
Verebelyi, I. 1998: Osszefoglal6 a kozigazgatasi reformfolyamat elso szakaszar61 es soron 
kovetkez6 feladatairol 1-2. (Summary on the first phase and further tasks of the public 
administrative reform process 1-2.). —  Magyar Kozigazgakis.  6. pp. 321-337., 7. pp. 
414-422. 
41 




Discussion Papers 2001. No. 35. 
Regional Development and Governance in Hungary
The  Discussion Papers series of the Centre for Regional Studies of the Hungarian 
Academy of Sciences was launched in 1986 to publish summaries of research findings 
on regional and urban development. 
The series has 5 or 6 issues a year. It will be of interest to geographers, economists, so-
ciologists, experts of law and political sciences, historians and everybody else who is, 
in one way or another, engaged in the research of spatial aspects of socio-economic 
development and planning. 
The series is published by the Centre for Regional Studies. 
Individual copies are available on request at the Centre. 
Postal address 
Centre for Regional Studies of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences 
P.O. Box 199,7601 PECS, HUNGARY 
Phone: (36-72) 212-755,233-704 
Fax: (36-72) 233-704 
www.dti.rkk.hu  
www.rkk.hu  
Director general 
Gyula HORVATH 
Editor 
Zoltan GAL 
Galz@dti.rkk.hu  
Forthcoming in the Discussion Papers series 
Role of the Regions in the Enlarging European Union 
Special Conference Issue 

Discussion Papers 2001. No. 35. 
Regional Development and Governance in Hungary
Papers published in the Discussion Papers series 
No. 1 
OROSZ, Eva (1986): Critical Issues in the Development of Hungarian Public Health 
with Special Regard to Spatial Differences 
No. 2 
ENYEDI, Gyorgy — ZENTAI, Viola (1986): Environmental Policy in Hungary 
No. 3 
HAJDU, Zoltan (1987): Administrative Division and Administrative Geography in 
Hungary 
No. 4 - SIKOS T., Tam& (1987): Investigations of Social Infrastructure in Rural Settlements 
of Borsod County 
No. 5 
HORVATH, Gyula (1987): Development of the Regional Management of the Econ- 
omy in East-Central Europe 
No. 6 
PALNE KOVACS, Ilona (1988): Chance of Local Independence in Hungary 
No. 7 
FARAGO, Laszlo — HRUBI, Laszlo (1988): Development Possibilities of Backward 
Areas in Hungary 
No. 8 
SZORENYINE KUKORELLI, ken (1990): Role of the Accessibility in Develop- 
ment and Functioning of Settlements 
No. 9 
ENYEDI, Gyorgy (1990): New Basis for Regional and Urban Policies in East- 
Central Europe 
No. 10 
RECHNITZER, Janos (1990): Regional Spread of Computer Technology in Hungary 
No. 11 
SIKOS T., Tamas (1992): Types of Social Infrastructure in Hungary (to be  not pub- 
lished) 

No. 12 
HORVATH, Gyula — HRUBI, Laszlo (1992): Restructuring and Regional Policy in 
Hungary 
No. 13 
ERDOSI, Ferenc (1992): Transportation Effects on Spatial Structure of Hungary 
No. 14 
PALNE KOVACS, Ilona (1992): The Basic Political and Structural Problems in the 
Workings of Local Governments in Hungary 
No. 15 
PFEIL, Edit (1992): Local Governments and System Change. The Case of a Regional 
Centre 
No. 16 
HORVATH, Gyula (1992): Culture and Urban Development (The Case of Pecs) 
No. 17 
HAJDU, Zoltan (1993): Settlement Network Development Policy in Hungary in the 
Period of State Socialism (1949-1985) 
No. 18 
KOVACS, Terez (1993): Borderland Situation as It Is Seen by a Sociologist 
No. 19 
HRUBI, L. — KRAFTNE SOMOGYI, Gabriella (eds.) (1994): Small and medium- 
sized firms and the role of private industry in Hungary 
No. 20 
BENKONE Lodner, Dorottya (1995): The Legal-Administrative Questions of 
Environmental Protection in the Republic of Hungary 
No. 21 
ENYEDI, Gyorgy (1998): Transformation in Central European Postsocialist 
Cities 
No. 22 
HAJDU, Zoltan (1998): Changes in the Politico-Geographical Position of Hun- 
gary in the 20th Century 

Discussion Papers 2001. No. 35. 
Regional Development and Governance in Hungary
No. 23 HORVATH, Gyula (1998): Regional and Cohesion Policy in Hungary 
No. 24 
BUDAY-SANTHA, Attila (1998): Sustainable Agricultural Development in the 
Region of the Lake Balaton 
No. 25 
LADOS, Mihaly (1998): Future Perspective for Local Government Finance in 
Hungary 
No. 26 
NAGY, Erika (1999): Fall and Revival of City Centre Retailing: Planning an Ur- 
ban Function in Leicester, Britain 
No. 27 BELUSZKY, Pal (1999): The Hungarian Urban Network at the End of the Sec-
ond Millennium 
No. 28 
RACZ, Lajos (1999): Climate History of Hungary Since the 16 th  Century: Past, 
Present and Future 
No. 29 
RAVE, Simone (1999): Regional Development in Hungary and Its Preparation 
for the Structural Funds 
No. 30 
BARTA, Gyorgyi (1999): Industrial Restructuring in the Budapest 
Agglomeration 
No. 31 BARANYI, Bela—BALCSOK, Istvan—DANCS, Laszlo—MED:5, Barna (1999): 
Borderland Situation and Peripherality in the North-Eastern Part of the Great 
Hungarian Plain 
No. 32 
RECHNITZER, Janos (2000): The Features of the Transition of Hungary's Re- 
gional System 
No. 33 MURANYI, Istvan—PETER, Judit—SZARVAK Tibor—SZOBOSZLAI, Zsolt 
(2000): Civil Organisations and Regional Identity in the South Hungarian Great 
Plain 
No. 34 KOVACS, Ter& (2001): Rural Development in Hungary