Discussion Papers 2001. No. 34. 
Rural Development in Hungary
 
CENTRE FOR REGIONAL STUDIES 
OF HUNGARIAN ACADEMY OF SCIENCES 
 
DISCUSSION PAPERS 
 
 

No. 34 
Rural Development in Hungary 
by 
Teréz KOVÁCS 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

Series editor 
Zoltán GÁL 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

Pécs 
2001 

Discussion Papers 2001. No. 34. 
Rural Development in Hungary
 
Publishing of this paper is supported by the 
Research and Publishing Fund of the Centre for Regional Studies, Hungary 
and 
the National Selected Social Sciences Research Fund (OKTK) No. A–1128/97. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
ISSN 0238–2008 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
2000 by Centre for Regional Studies of the Hungarian Acady of Sciences 
Technical editor: Ilona Csapó, Zoltán Gál 
Typeset by Centre for Regional Studies of HAS Printed in Hungary by Sümegi 
Nyomdaipari, Kereskedelmi és Szolgáltató Ltd., Pécs 
 

Discussion Papers 2001. No. 34. 
Rural Development in Hungary
CONTENTS 
 
 
 
Introduction  / 7 
1  Historic background  / 7 
2  The situation of agriculture ten years after the political transformation  / 9 
3  The problems of rural development  / 12 
4  The general situation of rural areas after the political transformation  / 15 
5  The diverse development of rural areas  / 18 
6  The role of agriculture in rural income  / 20 
7  Rural development policy in Hungary  / 21 
8  Integrated rural development  / 22 
8.1  Interdisciplinary approach  / 23 
8.2  Integration of economic sectors  / 25 
8.3  Integration of cities and villages  / 27 
8.4  Integration of rural society  / 28 
9  Hungarian rural development objectives  / 29 
10  The SAPARD Programme in Hungary  / 31 
11  Rural development in Hungary after the EU accession  / 36 
12 Summary 
 
/ 39 
References  / 41

Discussion Papers 2001. No. 34. 
Rural Development in Hungary
List of Tables 
 
 
Table 1  The division of population by dwelling and the rate of agricultural 
wage  earners   / 8 
Table 2  The agricultural population of Hungary, the number of farms, the size 
of land and animal livestock in year 2000  / 10 
Table 3   The distribution of farms by agricultural land size  / 11 
Table 4  Development categories of the villages  / 19 
Table 5  The Share of East European Countries from the EU Preaccession 
Funds  / 31 
Table 6  The distribution of SAPARD funds  / 32 
Table 7  The financial budget of the fifteen member countries for the period 
2001–2006  /38 
 
List of Figures 
 
Figure 1  The spatial distribution of the Hungarian agricultural export between 
1989 and 1998  / 12 
 
 
 
 
 

 




Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Introduction 
To understand Hungary’s rural development policy at the moment when Hun-
gary is standing at the doorstep of the EU accession it is essential to recall some 
important moments in the history of Hungarian agriculture. Rural development 
is discussed here mainly from sociological aspects, thus this paper is going to 
present only the basic statistical data to reveal the most important interrelations. 
1 Historic 
background 
Between the first and the second world wars Hungary was a country of semi-
feudal big landlords. Although the number of big landowners was below one 
per cent of the total population, the land they had was over 40 per cent of the 
total land territory. At the same time 28 per cent of rural population had no land 
at all and another 24 per cent had a land on a territory below 7 acres. Agricul-
tural reform was the only hope for rural Hungarians, which reform arrived in 
1945. About 600 thousand families who had no or small land were given land 
property on an average land size of 7 acres. This gave a chance for these people 
to start their business on 1.4 million farms in a good atmosphere. However the 
happiness of new farmers did not last long. In the summer of 1948 the Commu-
nist Party came on rule and they made a political harassment against kulaks 
(wealthy peasants). This prevented the social evolution of peasantry towards a 
middle class society. The development of Hungarian rural society was in the 
hand of external forces. 
In 1949 63 per cent of Hungarian population lived in rural villages and 54 
per cent worked in agriculture (Table 1). Fifty years later, in 1999 36.5 per cent 
lived in rural villages and 7.1 per cent worked in agriculture. This fifty-year 
period is characterised by the collapse of the traditional peasant society, which 
was a very fast process in Hungary. While in Britain one hundred years, in 
Germany eighty years were needed for this process, in Hungary the rate of agri-
cultural wage earners dropped from fifty per cent to twenty five per cent within 
twenty years only (1950–1970). The organisation of Soviet type cooperative 
farms was a further assistance to the disintegration of the traditional rural peas-
ant society.1  The organisation of cooperatives took place in two stages. 
                                                      
1 The Soviet type collectivisation differed from the Western European in its 
complete elimination of private property. Also the production took place in the 
cooperative system. 
 
7

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Table 1 
The division of population by dwelling and the rate of agricultural wage earners 
 (thousand) 
Year  S e t t l e m e n t  The rate of ac-
 Budapest 
Other 
cities 
Villages  Total 
tive agricultural 
wage earners 
  People % People % People
% People
% People

1949  1590 17.3 1774 19.3 5841 63.4 9205 100.0 3171 53.9 
1960  1783 17.9 2633 26.4 5345 65.7 9961 100.0 2227 38.7 
1970  2001 19.4 3109 30.1 5212 50.5 10322 100.0 1550 25.7 
1980  2060 19.2 3642 34.0 5008 45.8 10710 100.0 943  18.6 
1990  2017 19.4 4400 42.4 3958 38.2 10375 100.0 639  14.2 
1991  2018 19.5 4418 42.6 3919 37.9 10355 100.0 710  15.2 
1992  2016 19.5 4461 43.1 3861 37.4 10337 100.0 460  14.3 
1993  2008 19.5 4504 43.7 3790 36.8 10310 100.0 392  10.1 
1994  1996 19.3 4562 44.5 3719 36.2 10277 100.0 327  8.7 
1995  1930 18.8 4500 43.9 3816 37.3 10246 100.0 295  8.0 
1996  1907 18.7 4515 44.2 3790 37.1 10212 100.0 302  8.0 
1997  1886 18.5 4539 44.6 3749 36.9 10174 100.0 288  7.9 
1998  1863 18.4 4519 44.6 3753 37.0 10135 100.0 278  7.5 
1999  1839 18.2 4570 45.3 3682 36.5 10091 100.0 270  7.1 
Source: Hungarian Statistical Yearbooks. KSH. 
 
 
The first phase of collectivisation started in the early 1950s. It was typical in 
this process that small landowners, or agricultural workers who had no land or 
experience in farming who were forced to join the new cooperatives. Commu-
nist party activists who had no competence in agricultural matters headed these 
cooperatives. The cooperatives that were formed at that time were very unsuc-
cessful in business and showed negative example. After the death of Stalin 
(1953) these cooperatives ceased. 
The second phase of collectivisation started after the breakdown of the 1956 
revolution (1959–1961). The communist party (bearing the name of Hungarian 
Socialist Workers’ Party) learned from the negative experiences of the first 
round of collectivisation. In the second round the best agricultural experts were 
appointed as heads of cooperatives. Though it was a hard job but agricultural 
workers could be persuaded to join cooperatives. By 1961 only 4 per cent of the 
total agricultural land was in private hands, the remaining 96 per cent of land 
belonged to cooperatives and state farms. 
For all the initial problems and the use of methods being far from a peasant’s 
mentality Hungarian agriculture achieved success in the socialist era. The 
8   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
essence of this phenomenon is that the less Hungarian agriculture followed the 
Soviet model the more successful it was. However this rapid development of 
agriculture was paid at a high price at a later time. 
In Hungary (between the late 1960s and the early 1980s) a technological and 
biological modernisation took place. This was the industrialisation of agricul-
ture. At that time the generation of old peasants and cooperative founders re-
tired. There were two groups were to follow them; the first, smaller group was 
the elite group of qualified agricultural intelligence, expertise and agricultural 
workers. The second, large group was the group of less skilled and unskilled 
farmers. The first group gained income not only from their full-time job. In 
many cases they earned money from special large-scale part time farming ac-
tivities. The second group’s part time farming was only subsistence farming. 
The group of subsistence farmers also consisted of villagers commuting to cities 
for jobs in the industry. (In the mid 1980s 50 per cent of the total vegetable and 
fruit production and animal husbandry was done in private farms. Only cereal 
crop production was done in cooperatives and state farms). Both experts and 
unskilled farmers specialised their production and were profit oriented. They 
had different value preferences from their ancestors who were in love with their 
land and who were farming only to provide food for their family

The situation of agriculture ten years after the political 
transformation 

In Hungary the total size of arable land is 4.7 million hectares, 63 per cent of 
the total fertile land. The soil and climatic features are good for crop production. 
Although only 260 thousand wage earners work in agriculture (Table 1) the 
number of people living on agriculture is far larger. On the basis of the situation 
on 21 March 2000 the Hungarian Central Statistical Office made a census. This 
census provides statistical data on farmers and the size of their business. The 
criteria of the term agricultural farming unit included in the census were as 
follows: 
1.  1500 square metres of arable land or 
2.  500 square metres of orchard or vineyard or 
3.  Breeding at least one large animal (cow, ship, pig, etc.) or 
4.  50 items of poultry or 
5.  25 items of rabbit or 
6.  5 honeybee families or 
7.  Rendering agricultural services or dealing with interactive gardening (e.g. 
hothouse plantation) 


Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
The agricultural survey covers the data of 2.1 million households (that is 
nearly two thirds of the total). 960 thousand met the required criteria. Another 
835 thousand were below the criteria set up for land size or livestock. (Table 2) 
Besides individual farmers 8000 agricultural companies (agricultural share 
companies, ltd-s, and cooperatives) were assessed in the census. From the firms 
and entrepreneurs interviewed 300 thousand did not do any agricultural activi-
ties. The results indicate that half of the total households are interested in some 
agricultural business. 
Table 2 
The agricultural population of Hungary, the number of farms,  
the size of land and animal livestock in year 2000 
Agricultural business indicators 
Population (thousand)  Agricultural companies 
Private farms 
Non farms 
2035.5 
8382 
958 534 
835 617 
Agricultural land use indicators 
Total agricultural land 
Total 
Agricultural companies
Private farms 
used by (thousand 
6448 
3834 
2614 
hectares) 
Stock breeding indicators 
Total animal livestock 
Farms 
Agricultural companies
Private farms 
raised in 
1 665 181 
888 122 
777 059 
Animal units* 
*An average calculated on a variety of animals. One unit equals with 500 kgs (1000 pounds) of 
livestock or animal groups e.g. 1 cow = 0.8 animal units, 1 turkey = 0.13 animal units. 
Source: Magyarország mezőgazdasága a 2000. évben (Agriculture in Hungary in the year of 
2000.) regional date. Budapest, KSH, 2000. 
 
Private farmers cultivate 40 per cent of total agricultural land and 60 per cent 
is cultivated by agricultural companies. The size of the majority of private farms 
is below 0.5 hectares and only 5 per cent of private farms exceed the size of 10 
hectares. (Table 3) Agricultural companies have big lands. From the 8 thousand 
firms every fifth own a property of 1000–5000 hectares. Although the total 
number of livestock raised by farmers and agricultural companies is almost 
equal, the latter concentrates the majority of cow and pig stock. Other domestic 
animals are raised in private farms. 
Table 3 
The distribution of farms by agricultural land size 
10   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Private farms 
Agricultural companies 
Land size 
Percentage Land 
size Percentage 
(hectares) 
(hectares) 

0.15 28.63 
  –
10.0  12.71 
0.15 –
0.50 32.48 
10.1 –
50.0  21.13 
0.51 –
1.00 1.79 
50.1 –
100.0  9.65 
1.10 –
5.00 18.52 
100.1 –
300.0  19.51 
5.10 – 10.00 4.39 
300.1 –
500.0  5.32 
10.10 – 50.00 4.47 
500.1 – 1000.0  9.85 
50.10 – 100.00 0.48 
1000.1 – 5000.0  20.07 
100.10 – 300.00 0.22 
5000.1 – 10000.0  0.91 
300.10 –
 0.03 
10000.1 –  
0.84 
 Total 
100.00 
Total 
100.0 
Source: Magyarország mezőgazdasága a 2000. évben (Agriculture in Hungary in the year of 
2000.) regional date. Budapest, KSH, 2000. 
In 1990 15.3 per cent of the GDP came from agriculture. This figure dropped 
to 5.5 by the year 1999. Nevertheless, the agricultural sector produced an extra 
income of 1.5–2 billion dollars. This money was a significant help to keep 
Hungary’s foreign trade deficit on low level. The target areas of Hungarian 
agricultural export are the European Union, the countries of East Central 
Europe, and the countries of the former Soviet Union (Figure 1). The primary 
agricultural products that are exported to the exported to the European Union 
are as follows: meat and meat products, vegetables and fruits. The overall pro-
duction volume of Hungarian agricultural products is below 5 per cent of the 
production of the 15 EU member states. Only the following products are ex-
ceptions: 
−  Wheat, apple, cucumber, duck meat with 5–10 per cent 
−  Corn, sour cherry, plum with 10–20 per cent 
−  Honey, raspberry, sunflower with over 20 per cent of the total EU pro-
duction. 
11 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Figure 1 
The spatial distribution of Hungarian agricultural export 
between 1989 and 1998 
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
Other
CIS 2
CEEC1
EFTA
EU
 
1.  Central and Eastern European Countries (with the exclusion of the former Soviet Union) 
2.  The former Soviet Union 
Sources: Magyar Mezőgazdaság (Hungarian Agriculture) 2000. 43. 11. p. 
3  The problems of rural development 
Some problems of Hungarian rural areas date back to the past centuries, decades 
and the period after the political transformation. In this chapter I am going to 
overview the major problems of the past 70 years emphasizing on the socialist 
era and the problems that followed after the political transformation. The 
problems presented here stem from Hungary’s overall economic and political 
situation. 
In Hungary poverty is the deepest problem of rural areas. The peasant soci-
ety tried to ease this problem by various methods: by emigration before the First 
World War and by bringing up only one child to avoid the fragmentation of 
land properties. 
The equalisation of rural and urban incomes in Hungary was the greatest 
result in the 1970s, the booming time of socialism. This was a unique phe-
12   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
nomenon in East Central Europe. This was not due to the government’s rural 
policy
 but rather the result of the hard work of rural people. They had two 
sources of income. The first income came either from urban workplaces or from 
local industrial companies or agricultural cooperatives. The majority of rural 
people were progressing towards a bourgeois society. Now we are aware that 
this process was not completed. Rural workers after finishing their full-time job 
started their part-time job, which in most cases was bound to agriculture. They 
did it to earn an additional income for building a new house, a holiday cottage 
or purchasing furniture, car or other consumer goods. This was a great turn in 
the life of rural people, for they had never before spent their work or money for 
such purposes. 
The malfunctions in the socialist macroeconomic system – the uncompetitive 
and expensive production, the scarcity of goods – were improved by rural 
population, the millions who worked overtime in their second economy, turning 
the incompleteness of the system for their own benefit. Second economies were 
not real businesses
 in the original meaning of the word. There were no capital 
investments made, there was no urge for bearing risks in production and selling. 
It was cooperatives and state farms that were real investors and integrated pro-
duction and market instead of private farmers. They also undertook the partial 
or full risks of production, which made the job of integrated farms simpler, 
easier and more comfortable. 
After the political transformation the termination of jobs and integrated firms 
forced the majority of agricultural farms to minimise their production or to close 
down. It became obvious that the majority of those rural farmers who had lost 
their job closed their farm as well. They were following the patterns they had 
taken up in their full-time job in cities, in their part-time economy. These rural 
people were living in a safe atmosphere of their workplace, being dependent 
from others. When they lost their job, they lost their confidence, their future 
plans and feeling helpless they abandoned their farms as well. This made them 
even poorer. This process is a pretty good example how working patterns 
influence on people. That is the reason why the rate of the poorest has tripled in 
villages compared to cities, and quadrupled compared to Budapest, as it was 
indicated in ANDORKA, Rudolf’s survey. However, the rate of the top classes 
in handicapped villages is one seventh of those in Budapest. Pauperisation is 
much bigger in villages because the chances of social evolution are very small 
there. 
The second major problem of rural society is its limited chances for social 
evolution. This going to be discussed  
1.  In comparison within rural society and 
2.  In comparison between villages and cities 
13 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Until the redistribution of land in 1945, good-quality and large lands were in 
the hands of semi-feudal landlords. This created a rigid subordination system 
between the elite and poor peasant society. In his book ‘Elfelejtett falu’ (Village 
Out of Memory) KOPÁTSY Sándor says: ‘the old rural society has been 
poisoned by property, nationality and clerical limitations. They all were practi-
cably unbeatable. In this aspect our villages seem to have been left in the middle 
ages. The radical collectivisation has beaten down these property, nationality 
and clerical limitations.’ (11. p.) 
This is the reason why rural social disparities significantly decreased in the 
socialist era. Families living on primary and secondary incomes were able to 
create normal living conditions for themselves. After the political transforma-
tion this kind of stability ceased. This is the reason why it is the stability of their 
existence that rural people feel much more important than free press, free 
competition, or decreasing inflation or improving living conditions. In the so-
cialist era the stability these people got used to and feel very important, hin-
dered real social development. That’s why rural people were unable to benefit 
from market economy. 
ENYEDI, György in his book ‘Falvaink sorsa’ (The Fortune of Our 
Villages) published in 1980 says: ‘Urban and rural development in case of cities 
proves to be a public but in case of villages seems to be a private affair.’ (54. p.) 
This process – in a paradox way – lessened social differences within rural 
communities but increased differences between rural and urban settlements. 
The smaller a community was the worse position it had within the settlement 
system. In the ‘golden age’ of socialism the living conditions of 1.5 million 
rural people were worse than those living in more advantageous areas. There 
were no infrastructure and service development in about one half of villages. 
One of the greatest results of the rural development policy of the post-socialist 
era is the enormous effort to bridge development gaps between rural and urban 
settlements. In 1993, for example, 47 per cent of development funds were spent 
on rural development purposes. This significantly improved water and drainpipe 
infrastructure, school gym hall facilities, telephone and gas networks in rural 
areas. This is a large improvement, in compared to the 1970s when 7 per cent of 
funds were spent for rural development, whereas one half of the total population 
lived on rural areas at that time. 
The decline of rural communities is the third major problem of Hungarian 
rural areas. 
The traditional peasant community of the period between the two world wars 
was based on the family instead of the individual. Only grown-ups – through 
their family – could join various circles, groups and self-organised business 
associations. (e.g. pasturing committees, foresters’ companies, wine cellar 
cooperatives etc.) These associations worked in the form of a community and 
were operated democratically. The leaders were elected on a rotational basis. 
14   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Thus, local communities had an enormous initiative force. Community 
membership  created a  feeling of cohesion and protection, a sense of identity 
and confidence. Communities could have been a good starting point for later 
civil organisations and private initiatives but the Hungarian Communist Party 
banned all communities that were organised on social basis. Thus, individuals 
were deprived of self-organised, community activities. The whole society was 
atomised. With changes in the job and housing situation the role of family as a 
value model significantly decreased. The socialist system by making people 
believe in the illusion of a powerful, caring society and creating a sense of fear, 
deprived its citizens of self-reliance, self-knowledge and initiations. 
Apart from some exceptions, the majority of local civil organisations having 
been established since 1989 were too weak to have a major influence on rural 
development. Good communities may be the driving force of local development. 
The communist type rural development gives no alternative for community 
based development. In the old times natural rules were set up by life itself. We 
should not bring back these old rules again but a new well-operating system 
should be set up on the basis of the present situation. To achieve this objective 
chances should be given to handicapped rural residents to find their way out of 
their crisis. 
4  The general situation of rural areas after the 
political transformation 
After the political transformation villages had both positive and negative phe-
nomena in the history of their development. 
The positive elements are as follows: 
1.  A local government was set up in every village 
2.  A significant progress has been made in rural infrastructure 
The negative elements are as follows: 
1.  The growth of unemployment 
2.  The cutback of agricultural production 
Elected local authorities make decisions on local development projects. It 
was small villages that were mostly dependant from state assistance having no 
incomes from local taxation. In the early 1990s 36-37 per cent of active wage 
earners and 48 per cent of the unemployed lived in rural settlements. Unem-
ployment was much higher in rural areas (13.8 per cent) than the national aver-
age. (10.4 per cent in 1998) Villages below the population of 500 had extremely 
high unemployment. At the same time agricultural production dropped to 60 per 
15 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
cent of the level it had in 1989. It was stock farming that decreased the most 
sharply.  
The reader may be on the opinion that today, ten years after the political 
transformation, the majority of Hungarian rural settlements are the losers of the 
political transformation. However, while the number of Hungary’s total popu-
lation is decreasing, the rate of rural population has remained on the same level, 
nevertheless, occasionally it has even increased. The year 1994 was the first 
year when the number of rural population was on the bottom after the political 
transformation (3719 thousand) but a 4-year increase started in the following 
year 1995. However, in 1999 only 3682 thousand lived in rural areas. This 
number is the largest negative record in the 1990s, being below the first one in 
1994 (Table 1). In countries with advanced economy the growth of rural popu-
lation is the result of de-urbanisation, the migration of middle class to rural 
settlements. The question here is why the number of rural population increased 
if rural areas are regarded to be the losers of political transformation? 
There are three reasons for the growth of rural population in Hungary. They 
are suburbanisation, migration and handicapped social position. 
1. Suburbanisation. In the socialist era council flats were built only in cities. 
Rural residents built their house themselves. Since the mid–1980s villagers 
were paid state assistance to solve their housing problems. At the same time the 
building of council flats dropped in cities. As a result, blue- and white-collar 
city workers built their house in the agglomeration area of the cities they 
worked in. Living and commuting from within a 50 kilometre (30 mile) radius 
of Budapest and from within a 30 kilometre (20 mile) radius of large cities be-
came a popular social phenomenon. However, the increase in purchasing power 
resulting from the migration of rich and educated social classes to rural areas 
did not generate a booming rural economy. Those wealthy people who live in 
villages travel to cities for shopping, because those services they need are 
available in cities only. Taking children to city kindergartens and schools is an 
example for their attitude to rural services. Thus, suburbanisation increases the 
number of rural population but growth is not coupled with local identity. The 
migration of blue- and white –collar urban population is still to be regarded as a 
positive trend because it accelerates the progress of rural society towards a 
middle class society. 
2. Migration. In the period after the political transformation 200–220 thou-
sand people change their home every year. More than half are out-migrations to 
rural settlements. Rural areas have had a positive migration balance since 1989, 
while the balance of Budapest and large cities has been negative. Increasing 
urban housing costs are a reason for that. This is especially true in case of urban 
housing estates. Between 1995–1997 several old-age pensioners having 
purchased the council flat they lived in the socialist era sold it out on a much 
higher price. They could spend the profit they gained through this transaction 
16   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
for a rural house. They could purchase a house either in the proximity of their 
previous flat, or in their home village or somewhere else. Typically the urban 
poor and the elderly migrated to rural areas in this way, which further increased 
the average age of rural people and their need for the young, educated genera-
tion. This problem is extremely deep because it is only the young generation 
that may be expected to find solutions for the problems of rural areas. 
3. Handicapped social position. The unskilled rural residents are the greatest 
losers of the political transformation. They are mainly gypsies. Their low 
education is coupled with low work culture and the absence of venture capital. 
Thus, they have no chances on the labour market. In the socialist era nobody 
was allowed to make capital investments. Those coming from families that were 
poor before the political transformation got into a “no way out” situation after 
losing their job having provided them a small but stabile income. This group 
lives only on child-care allowance and various social benefits. Houses without 
infrastructure are more frequent in rural than urban areas. They have lower 
maintenance costs. This is the reason why rural areas are more attractive for the 
poor. The rate of gypsies is extremely high in Hungary’s northeastern and 
southwestern small village areas. The demographic features of gypsies and 
Hungarians of similar social situation (early age maternity, large number of 
children) largely contribute to the growth of rural population. Hungarian rural 
policy should concentrate on providing extra development funds to these so-
cially disadvantaged areas. These funds should be used for the education of 
gypsies and poor Hungarians to improve their labour market chances. The pro-
vision of assistance to subsistence farming is also a very important task. Farm-
ing was natural in the old traditional peasant society, but now it won’t work 
without help. In general, it is much easier to apply for grants and benefits than 
doing something actively. 
In the past few years the number of non-Hungarian residents has signifi-
cantly increased in rural areas. Since 1993, it is county public administration 
authorities that have licenses to authorise foreigners for purchasing real estates 
in Hungary. Until 1993 the Centre for the Financial Institutions of Hungary, 
seated in Budapest, had competence over these matters. With the exception of 
agricultural land the purchase of Hungarian real estates by foreigners was a very 
easy and simple process. Low prices, quiet and peaceful rural landscape 
attracted buyers from the European Union and America. These people spend 
only a part of their time in Hungary. Generally they ask a caretaker to look after 
their house while they are away. In some instances a whole village is in the 
hand of foreign landowners. The surroundings of Lake Balaton, the western and 
southwestern rural areas are the most popular among foreigners. The scattered 
farms of the Great Hungarian Plain are also very popular. Generally the first 
buyer brings additional buyers. The good side of this matter is that foreign citi-
zens generally improve the outlook of the site the bad thing is that no state as-
17 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
sistance is received for foreigners because they are not permanent residents. In 
villages with natives outweighed by foreigners, it is a real threat that public 
services (e.g. schools) will terminate due to financial problems.  
5  The diverse development of rural areas 
In Hungary there were always large differences among settlement categories. 
Budapest the capital changed into a metropolis at the turn of the 19th and 20th 
centuries. Hungary lost her major regional centres after the peace treaties that 
followed the First World War. Apart from some major cities at the western part 
with Debrecen and Szeged in the eastern regions the majority of Hungarian 
settlements were small agricultural towns with a small city centre and rural style 
buildings. In the socialist era large efforts were made towards the development 
of these small agricultural towns. However the number of new jobs created was 
more than the number of new flats built. The majority of workers were forced to 
daily commuting. In the late 1970s the ‘golden age’ of socialism 1.5 million 
people one quarter of total active wage earners were commuting to work in 
cities.  
No financial resources were available for flat construction and infrastructure 
development in rural areas. In the 1980s flat construction started in large vil-
lages because state assistance was given to rural flat construction instead of 
urban council flats. Although state assistance was able to initiate the construc-
tion of new homes, no funds were available for infrastructure development 
projects. After the political transformation extensive – in some instances irra-
tional – development projects were launched in rural areas. In the early 1990s, 
the per head indicators of infrastructure development were higher in rural than 
in urban areas. Large progress has been made in the construction of telephone, 
public road, water, drainpipe gas systems and schools. For all this progress, due 
to heavy unemployment, the absence of foreign venture capital and poor human 
resources, the overall development indicators of rural areas were below the 
expectations. Today three categories of rural areas exist (Table 4). 
18   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Table 4  
Development categories of the villages 
Category of village 
Village 
Population 
  P e r c e n t a g e  
1. Viable 
20 
40 – 50 
2. Underdeveloped 
30 
20 
3. In transition 
50 
30 – 40 
Source: The author’s assessment. 
1. Viable villages. 20 per cent of villages and almost half of the total rural 
population belong to this category. These villages are scattered around the 
country but mostly in the proximity of major roads and cities offering good job 
opportunities. The popular hillside recreational villages offering facilities for 
rural tourism also belong to this category. The majority is situated along the 
Vienna–Budapest route. This area and the agglomeration of Budapest are the 
most advanced Hungarian regions. In viable villages the representation of blue 
and white-collar population is starting to outweigh the native locals. The white 
and blue-collar population who had run away from cities largely contributed to 
giving a middle-class feature to the traditional rural class society. Here the 
number of SME-s also shows an increasing tendency. 
2. Underdeveloped villages. 30 per cent of villages and 20 per cent of the 
total rural population belong to this category. These villages are located in un-
derdeveloped areas far from cities. They are also available along county or 
eastern country borders and have poor transport connections. These areas have 
poor quality arable land or bumpy land surface. These villages are scattered 
around the country but most frequently occur in northeastern and southwestern 
Hungary. The majority are small villages with a population below 500. Public 
facilities were closed in the socialist era. The establishment of local authorities 
after the political transformation did not improve their overall situation. These 
villages have low educated, poor Hungarian and gypsy population. Here the 
majority of families live on child care allowance, some benefits and odd jobs. 
The rate of the poor is quadruple the rate of the wealthy class is one seventh of 
Budapest the capital. Pauperisation is looking forward to be a durable tendency 
in these areas. 
3. Villages in transition. They are neither in top nor in bottom situation. One 
half of villages and 30-40 per cent of the total population belong to this cate-
gory. The majority of the local population are lower middle class or poor peo-
ple. They do nothing but wait. They have a house, furniture, the husband or the 
wife or both have a job. They do some part-time farming but it provides low 
income for them. Even the education of children is a problem for these families. 
19 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Due to the drastic increase of urban housing costs several old-age pensioners 
were forced to move from cities to rural areas where living costs are smaller. A 
gas heated urban flat’s maintenance costs are much higher than the costs of a 
rural house with a garden. A rural house may be heated traditionally (by wood 
or coal) and by heating only some rooms instead of the full house a lot of 
money may be saved in winter. Rural houses have a separate water meter, 
which measure individual water consumption. Urban blocks of flats have only 
one common water-meter. In this system total water consumption is divided on 
a per head basis according to the number of families. 
In my opinion Hungarian rural policy should support transitional villages so 
that they would not turn backward. At the same time rural policymakers should 
prepare various strategies for the most handicapped rural areas. Here the im-
provement of human resources is the most important. Now the real threat is that 
if Hungary joins the European Union, a large number of people living now in 
backward areas, will emigrate into countries that are more advanced than Hun-
gary. The Hungarians are well aware that these people should remain and be 
supported where they live now. Unfortunately no funds are available for this 
purpose yet. 
6  The role of agriculture in rural income 
Fertile land is the most important – in some instances the only – natural re-
source of rural areas. For several centuries it was the only source of rural in-
come. Apart from Budapest and some major cities the whole Hungarian society 
was bound to land, it was their only income source. Agriculture was not only 
the business of agricultural farmers. It gave jobs for rural artisans – through 
agricultural tools and machinery repair service – and for lawyers who were 
administering the farmers’ estates and inheritance matters. In the early 20th 
century various agricultural businesses from milling industry through meat 
processing to various services that rural society was in need of started in Hun-
gary. After the extinction of the traditional peasant society these activities either 
survived in a new form or were terminated. In the socialist era villages had 
some industry. If rural industrial firms were selling their products to east Euro-
pean markets – and the majority did so – they went bankrupt after the political 
transformation. Rural services were very poor until the end of socialism. These 
facts mentioned clearly show that rural economy was in critical situation at the 
beginning of the political transformation and apart from some areas it is still in 
crisis. The question ‘How to make rural society viable?’ is still very topical. 
The privatisation of agriculture brought land for 2 million people. However 
only the minority of landowners deal with farming. Some have sold others have 
20   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
leased their land. I estimate the number of active farmers to be the least within 
this group.  
There are four groups of active rural population on the basis of income: 
Group 1: The primary income of group members comes from non-agricul-
tural sector. Agriculture in case of this group means subsistence farming in 
vegetable garden or on small land below the size of 1500 square meters. The 
lease of a maximum 3-hectare land also might occur here. The majority of citi-
zens belong to this category. I estimate this group to 40-50 per cent of the active 
rural population. They either can afford to give up farming or unable to do it 
and for this reason they lease their land. Agriculture is not really important for 
them. 
Group 2: Group members have their own farm and they do farming as man-
agers or members of private or agricultural companies. 10–15 per cent of the 
active rural population belong to this category. This group has maintained the 
original function of villages by continuous agricultural farming. The territory of 
their farms varies between 30 and 1000 hectares per family. Their employees 
have no private land they get monthly salary only. 
Group 3: Group members are part-time farmers only or lease their land if 
they have big land. Part time farming is typical in the EU and in Hungary it is 
also desirable to have more than one job. 10–15 per cent of active rural belong 
to this category. The typical farm size is between 5 and 50 hectares per family.  
Group 4: Group members have neither land no jobs, because they are either 
too young and the farm belongs to their parents or find no job on the job mar-
ket. 30–35 per cent of the active rural population belong to this category. They 
should get a job outside the agricultural sector. 
Due to the reasons mentioned, it seems that farms still have some role in ru-
ral income but this role is only a partial one giving potential life support and a 
sense of security for farmers. 
7  Rural development policy in Hungary 
Hungary’s EU accession and the gradual introduction of the EU acquis com-
munautaire system increased the role of rural development policy and its termi-
nology in Hungary’s scientific and political areas and press language. Our EU 
accession may end up in failure if EU patterns are disregarded by Hungarian 
rural development policy.  
It is very important that both in the European Union and Hungary rural de-
velopment policy is to treat rural employment problems and the excess of agri-
cultural population. For all these similarities rural development policy follows 
different patterns in the European Union and in Hungary. 
21 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
In the EU the revolution of the information technology – the second indus-
trial revolution – made possible to avoid considering rural development bring-
ing changes only for a minority of local communities. This has put an end to the 
illusion of the continuous growth theory. The problems of agricultural surplus 
show that the one-side profit orientation of production will generate waste, 
environmental pollution and will lead to deadlock in the evolution process. The 
concept of sustainable development was born as a response to this phenomenon. 
Sustainability demands putting the quality of life above the quantity aspects of 
consumption. In this respect sustainable development is closely related to rural 
areas. In the European Union rural development policy derives from a new 
philosophy of sustainable development and the opposition of globalisation. 
In Hungary rural development policy is associated with the backwardness of 
rural economy. The 1996. XXI. Act on Regional Development and Physical 
Planning with the 1997. CXIV. Act on the Development of Agricultural Econ-
omy serve as legal standpoints for Hungarian rural development. The govern-
ment elected in 1998 put rural development under the competence of the Min-
istry of Agriculture. Then the name of the Ministry was changed to Ministry of 
Agriculture and Rural Development. In January 1999 a Department of Rural 
Development Programmes was organised within the Ministry. 
8  Integrated rural development 
Article 2 of the 1996 Cork Declaration is about the integrated aspect of rural 
areas. The Declaration starts from the point that rural development policy must 
be multi-disciplinary in concept and multi-sectoral in application. These two 
principles are the most important in rural development but integration should 
cover a wider sphere. In Hungary rural development should cover the following 
areas: 
−  Interdisciplinary approach; 
−  Cross-sectoral integration; 
−  The integration of cities with villages; 
−  The integration of rural society; 
Integration should cover all areas mentioned here. Details will follow in the 
next chapters. 
8.1 Interdisciplinary 
approach 
In Hungary rural development concepts are integrated from multiple disciplines. 
This does not mean that all sciences that have something to do with rural 
22   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
development really do that. Compared to the rural disciplines of the European 
Union with the Hungarian the shortage of Hungarian macroeconomic experts 
seems to be a large gap. Hungarian rural development experts should express 
their opinion on rural policy to the public but so far they have not done it. In 
Hungary three research groups study rural development. These three are soci-
ologists, agricultural researchers and the experts of SAPARD (Special Acces-
sion Program for Agricultural Rural Development) Programme. They study 
different aspects pf rural development. 
1. The most comprehensive researches in rural development issues are car-
ried out by sociologists, namely by rural sociologists (together with some geog-
raphers of similar interest). Sociologists restarted their village sociology re-
searches in the 1980s. They were to revive and continue the old traditions of the 
rural sociology of the past. The majority who participated on village research 
group meetings (or discussions in rural research camps) in the 1980s are now 
publishing papers on various rural development issues and firmly state that 
there is an relationship between rural and regional policy. Although rural de-
velopment is an integral part of regional development they uses different poli-
cies through the realisation of their objectives. The elimination of regional dis-
parities is the fundamental objective of regional development. Regional devel-
opment is going to achieve this target through effective economic development. 
According to theory of regional development the extension of markets is an-
other reason why the situation of backward areas should be improved.  Rural 
development is also targeted to the elimination of regional disparities but it is 
going to achieve that through the improvement of peripheral areas. 
To sum it up, to achieve the same result 
−  Regional development is targeted for effective economic development; 
−  Rural development is targeted for the improvement of peripheral areas 
Obviously, effective economic development is an integral part of rural de-
velopment but rural development comprises the improvement of human re-
sources and the maintenance of local communities as well. 
2. Agricultural experts are the second group of rural development research-
ers. In the EU the institutional system of rural development has very close rela-
tionship with the agricultural sector because the EU is going to terminate its 
assistance to farmers within the system of Common Agricultural Policy, which 
was established in the Rome Treaty. The assistance Hungarian farmers receive 
now from the government is far less than the EU level. Today the direct assis-
tance the EU would provide to Hungarian farmers would be twenty times higher 
than the present level of state assistance. Among countries that have market 
economy and agricultural surplus only rich countries have modern agriculture. 
Very large sums were spent there for the modernisation of agriculture in the 
past years. Nearly all governments in rich countries protect and give support to 
23 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
agriculture. New Zealand is the only exception because in New Zealand 
agriculture was modernised instead of industry and the country turned to be 
prosperous in that way. Agriculture receives only 5 per cent support there.  
Although in Hungary only 7 per cent of the total population is a full-time 
farmer, agriculture is still a national identity symbol. This may be explained by 
the fact that in 1949 one half of the total active wage earners were living on 
agriculture and today still one half of the total families deals with part-time 
farming to save on food costs. 
The success of agriculture in the socialist era created the image of Hungary 
as “food pantry for Eastern Europe”. 
The emotional attitude towards agriculture is not only a Hungarian feature. 
European countries with modern agriculture (France, Finland, Austria) are also 
agriculture-minded and this is the reason for the survival of the assistance phi-
losophy of Common Agricultural Policy. 
Not only positive images are associated with agriculture. In Hungary a lot of 
experts worry about agriculture, saying, that this sector will be the loser of 
Hungary’s EU accession. To avoid this the term ‘profit-making agriculture’, 
regarded as the best alternative of rural policy, has been introduced. Those who 
are on this opinion think that agricultural grants should be given only to com-
petitive farms. This view suggests that rural development is only the result of 
agricultural development. 
3. Within the framework of the Hungarian programme of SAPARD, together 
with regional and county level programmes, various inter-settlement coopera-
tion projects were born, which served as a basis for micro-regional projects. As 
a result of cooperation, small workgroups are formed. Group members by 
writing their own SAPARD programme, may turn themselves into rural devel-
opment experts. These experts have various professional backgrounds. They 
consider  rural development as an instrument of stopping the disorders of a 
classical market economy
. These people represent the official part and may give 
a new approach to rural development. They may establish strong relationship 
and this may increase the social basis of rural development with the size of 
expert groups. Hungarian SAPARD experts hold the opinion that human re-
sources, various adult education programmes, environmental and educational 
objectives should receive priorities in rural development. They completely dis-
regard the aspects of competitive agriculture. It depends only themselves 
whether they remain rural experts or not in the future. This new expertise 
should tackle two problems. First, they are to write some articles into journals 
because their views on rural development issues have not been published in any 
papers. Second, their potential candidates to whom they write their proposals 
have no financial resources. If calls for tender are published for SAPARD proj-
ects, only those who can submit their tender will receive resources. I must tell, 
am afraid that development projects will proceed not in the same way that 
24   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
SAPARD programmers desired. It might turn out that all was nothing but illu-
sion and Hungarian SAPARD programmes will have to stop. 
A broader interdisciplinary approach to rural development requires two 
things: The first is that all rural scientist should publish their opinion in scien-
tific journals and the ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development should be 
responsible for the practical realisation of concepts. The second is a close co-
operation among different sciences serving as a basis for a sound rural devel-
opment policy. Rural development experts need various forums to express and 
discuss their views and opinions on meetings. 
8.2  Integration of economic sectors 
The rural economy of the socialist era was unable to survive the political trans-
formation. Due to the decrease of state assistance and the loss of European 
markets the overall volume of agricultural production dropped by 40 per cent. 
Rural industry was in an initial phase only and was unable to compete with the 
emerging products imported from West European countries. Rural services were 
very poor until the end of socialism. These are the reasons why rural economy 
was and apart from some instances it is still in crisis. Rural development may be 
achieved by an integrated development of various economic sectors. 
Concerning living and employment conditions, 10–15 per cent of rural 
population are full-time farmers another 10–15 per cent are part-time farmers. 
The rest work in cities or local industry or unemployed. 
Unemployment is the deepest problem of today’s rural society. The socialist 
era had full employment coupled with large-scale hidden unemployment. After 
the political transformation “phantom jobs” gradually ceased. In year 2000 the 
number of jobs were 25 per cent less than ten years before. Ordinary rural peo-
ple were unable to gain benefits from privatisation. This is particularly true in 
case of the uneducated rural. Some of them retired and live as old age or dis-
ability pensioners. These tricks of “pensioning off” were used to avoid unem-
ployment. The scarcity of jobs is the largest obstacle of rural development. The 
diversification of rural economy may be a solution for this problem. 
Hungary’s accession to the EU may accelerate rural development in two ar-
eas. The first is local resource based agricultural and non-agricultural activities 
– including food processing – because assistance will be given to these invest-
ments. The other area is local services that will be rendered for local residents 
and visitors. 
Agricultural support may have special role in rural development. Nobody 
knows yet the volume of the normative assistance Hungarian agriculture will 
receive from EU funds but it surely will be higher than the present sum of 22–
25 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
24 billion HUF Hungarian farmers receive from the budget now. This is espe-
cially true considering price changes. The question is that what purposes will 
this sum be spent for. Production costs the largest item in farmers’ budget will 
not increase only taxation will be heavier. The income farmers will gain from 
the increased assistance may either be spent on the modernisation of production 
or for the improvement of personal living conditions. After Greece’s EU acces-
sion in 1981 Greek farmers used the agricultural support they gained from the 
EU for the improvement of their personal living conditions. Although a part of 
this sum was really earmarked for these purposes, but actually it should have 
been spent for technical investments, and this did not happen. This is the reason 
of the low productivity of Greek agriculture coupled with low food consump-
tion. While in 1989 dairy production was 760 kg (1520 pounds) per head in the 
Netherlands, it was only 71 kg (142 pounds) per head in Greece. Even if Greece 
had a very low dairy consumption, it covered only 84 per cent. 
Hungary has a real threat to have the same tendency. The lack of small 
farming or multi-generation farming strategies may result in this. The increase 
in normative agricultural support after Hungary’s EU accession will increase 
differences between small and large farms, favouring for the latter. Agricultural 
support will not cover the costs of technical modernisation for small farmers. 
They may either spend the grants for other purposes or may cooperate through 
the realisation of common development projects. If they are unable to cooperate 
they could do the best by spending their money for the education or training of 
their children. In this way the young generation would not work in agriculture 
but could keep staying in villages. Their job qualifications in the service sector 
would provide good full-time jobs in small farms. Later on small farmer fami-
lies may terminate their agricultural activities and through the union of their 
lands they may grow the agricultural land of other families. This can result in a 
trend in which local money is spent locally.  
Although the level of food consumption cannot exceed a certain limit, its 
structure may undergo some transformation. The largest demand will be for 
various local services. Educating young people to be able to render services 
meeting local demands is our great task. Otherwise rural people will travel to 
cities and they will spend their money there. Local incomes should be spent 
locally and the income, circulating round the community, will serve for the 
overall benefit of local residents. 
In the EU the welfare of rural people is based on two policies. 
One is that the taxpayers’ money is redirected to rural areas to contribute to 
the income of rural farmers who are to sell their products on low prices of the 
global market. The other policy is also funded from the taxpayers’ money. It 
provides financial assistance to rural areas for rural regeneration, environment 
and landscape economy projects. This is a feasible practice because, on the one 
hand the European Union is a welfare society, on the other hand the sight of 
26   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
nice rural landscape gives a good image and atmosphere not only for the local 
people but for tourists and holiday visitors as well. The same reasons motivate 
environmental and landscape economy support projects. These projects serve 
for the overall benefit of the whole society. 
For a long time the European Union’s Common Agricultural Policy concen-
trated only on farmers’ assistance. It was only during the last ten years that its 
strategy moved towards rural development. Beyond economic reasons, the 
heritage of peaceful rural landscape is such a great value for the Europeans that 
they are ready to do their best to preserve it. If Hungary also turns into a welfare 
society, Hungarians will surely follow this model. Several problems should be 
tackled to achieve this. Here I would shortly define the tasks of local citizens, 
politicians and politics. Local citizens should learn or educate their children. 
Local politicians should make local citizens understand their tasks and convince 
them to keep staying in their home village. They should convince them that it is 
not good for a person or a family but it is good for the whole community. If a 
group is motivated by a good target staying in home village will be a natural, 
self sustaining process. Politics should make local politicians understand their 
mission. Their mission may be described as the enlightening of local residents. 
Politics should provide the necessary background of these enlightening 
functions. 
8.3  Integration of cities with villages 
Cities and their surrounding villages should be understood as an organic unit. 
Rural and urban settlements may not exist without each other. The integration 
of cities with surrounding villages, and locality are emphasized in this chapter. 
In 1990 the establishment of the local government system enabled villages to 
bring decisions by themselves on their future. However there are several matters 
that cannot be decided locally. The recognition of the need for inter-settlement 
cooperation and thinking in settlement groups instead of thinking locally is the 
next step from here. The development of services and other activities mentioned 
in the earlier chapter is feasible only within a micro regional system. The 
European Union’s policies are based on the coexistence of cities and their 
surroundings. In the European Union the relationship of cities and their 
surroundings is based on partnership and cooperation. If cooperation is set up 
between institutions only this will have a formal character only and won’t work. 
Following the rules of formal procedures – determined by bureaucracy and 
institutional capital – it is the leaders of cities and villages who should initiate 
cooperation. They should establish partnership with the majors of another 
27 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
settlements. They should convince the other partners that it is their programmes 
and ideas that are viable and worth for following. 
Micro regional cooperation should cover the following areas: 
−  Industrial and other economic policies 
−  Agricultural policy 
−  Environmental issues 
−  Regional development 
−  Employment policy 
−  Social policy 
8.4  Integration of rural society 
In 1887 Ferdinand Tönnies formulated his famous ‘Gemeinshaft-Gesselschaft’ 
theory. This theory says that villages are typical Gemeinshafts (communities) 
while cities are Gesselhafts (societies). In a community people are in a sound 
relationship. A community is an organisation based on face-to-face relations. In 
a society the situation is different: although people set up their everyday com-
municational relations they live separately, everybody is left alone and there is a 
constant tension between the individual and the others. Tönnies’ theory was 
working for a long time in the Hungarian society until the 1960s. Up to this date 
rural communities strongly depended on agriculture and wealthy farmers were 
put as examples for the others who were followed by the majority of rural 
farmers. After the collectivisation this system did not survive. 
In his survey in the early 1990s Andorka Rudolf came to the conclusion that 
occurrence of permanent poverty – the lowest level of subsistence – is almost 
seven times larger in villages than in Budapest. He also pointed out that rural 
population is in much lower mood than the urban.  
Thus, the mood indicator of rural population is than the Hungarian average 
being also low. Pessimism and loneliness are the most dominant form of feeling 
in villages.  
Today rural development is doomed to failure without the involvement and 
active cooperation of local residents but how can local society be more active 
without self-orientation, self-reliance, self-conscience and a strategy to tackle 
problems? 
If someone has no job, no money and is defenceless, he or she cannot be ac-
tivated until being given some opportunity to do something to live better. Even 
then, it is not sure he will really do something to turn better. Animation is in-
vented to help people who are unable to help themselves. The meaning of ani-
mation here is community reactivation, in other words, giving life to something. 
The animator here is a group helper activating a group to find their identity. 
28   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
With the animator’s help group members can find their place within the com-
munity and society. The cooperation and common activity of group members 
will initiate changes in the group members’ mind urging them to take the first 
steps to turn their life better. 
Community development may take place on two levels. The first is the level 
of agitation. Here the means of propaganda may be used. The target group may 
listen carefully and agree with the speaker, the agitator. Then the personal in-
volvement of local group members is required. Personal contacts should be 
established among group members. 
The role of personal character has greatly increased in our world of hidden 
values. If someone wants to help the community from outside, he or she should 
have a strong personal character. He should believe in his programme making 
others feel that they will get real help to find their way out of crisis. He should 
create a group from local people who are popular and respected among the oth-
ers. Through these group members positive live contacts may be established 
with the rest of community. 
Thus, local community members should be the animator’s closest assistants. 
9  Hungarian rural development objectives 
Hungarian rural development is targeted for rural economic development and 
the cutback of social disparities. To achieve these objectives rural development 
should carry out infrastructure development and human resource improvement 
projects.  
1. The consequences of agricultural modernisation on rural economy should 
be assessed by a survey. In places where the survey shows adequate conditions 
agriculture should either be extensive or intensive (bio-gardening). They need 
capital and cognitive management. Financial assistance should be based on 
programmes and projects associated with programmes should be funded. The 
manufacturing of products looking back to long-time traditions should have 
priorities in funding on micro regional level. Investments of strategic impor-
tance, such as freshwater fishing, irrigation or forest planting projects should 
have priorities on regional level.  
2. The diverse development of rural economy. The future of rural areas 
should not solely depend on agriculture. New sectors, new activities should be 
established in rural areas. The support of rural small enterprises, such as small-
scale food processing, rural industry, basic services, commerce, rural tourism, 
investment and manufacture consulting, public information services should 
have priorities in development.  
29 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
3. Infrastructure development. Although this is the area in which the greatest 
progress has been made since the political transformation the situation is still far 
from being appropriate. The development of public road and drainpipe systems 
will be an acute problem in rural areas for many years. The development of 
services strongly depends on infrastructure development. There is a large 
difference between the service need of native and middle class residents having 
recently moved to rural areas. This created a difficult situation for service 
industry investors. 
4. Human resource improvement has strong relations with the three above-
mentioned objectives. This includes the preparation of rural population for 
changes in their trading and enterprise activities and the risks they should bear 
in their business. People living in poor conditions have a feeling of inferiority. 
Gaining self-confidence should change this attitude. Responsibilities are shared 
in this field. Those having contacts with a large number of people (such as mass 
media institutions) have extremely high responsibility. It is a great threat that a 
large mass of communities are excluded from the European Union’s economic 
policy if rural areas remain unfit for integration after Hungary’s EU accession. 
Finally, it should be emphasized that rural development in Hungary is lag-
ging behind the transformation of the country’s central and other advanced 
regions. It also seems sure that rural transformation will coincide with Hun-
gary’s EU accession. This is another potential source of conflict for rural 
population who have still not recovered from the shock of political transforma-
tion.  
In the European Union the volume of rural development grants has a grow-
ing tendency. It is expected that the contribution Hungary will pay into the EU 
budget will be smaller than the grants Hungary will receive. A significant part 
of these EU grants will be allocated for regional and rural development pur-
poses. However grants are not transferred automatically, they should be won by 
projects in a very bureaucratic system. It is also expected that the overall vol-
ume of grants will be lower at the time of Hungary’s EU accession than now, so 
the competition for funds will be greater. Within this competition system Hun-
gary should elaborate the most effective model of rural development. 
10  The SAPARD Programme in Hungary 
In 1997 the EU – regarding the enlargement with East European countries – 
made a decision on the establishment of preaccession funds. These funds are the 
PHARE, (Poland-Hungary Assistance for Restructuring the Economy) the ISPA 
(The Instrument for Structural Policies for Pre-Accession) and the SAPARD. 
The SAPARD on the one hand assists to the execution of programmes within 
30   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
the framework of Common Agricultural Policy and its relevant tasks, on the 
other hand it is targeted towards tackling the primary and special problems of 
sustainable agricultural and rural development within the accession countries. 
The share of the East European countries from the EU preaccession grants 
varies from country to country (Table 5). 
Table 5 
The Share of East European Countries from the EU Preaccession Funds 
Country % 
Bulgaria  
8.0 
– 
12.0 
Czech Republic 
 
5.5 –  8.0 
Estonia  
2.0 
– 
3.5 
Poland  
30.0 
– 
37.0 
Latvia  
3.5 
– 
5.5 
Lithuania  
4.0 
– 
6.0 
Hungary  
7,0 
– 
10.0 
Romania  
20.0 
– 
26.0 
Slovakia  
3.5 
– 
5.5 
Slovenia  
1.0 
– 
2.0 
Total  
84.5 
– 
115.5 
Source: Magyar Mezőgazdaság (Hungarian Agriculture) 1999. 32. p. 8. 
The annual budget of SAPARD for the EU candidates is 520 million euros, 
which is funded from the EAGGF Guarantee fund (Table 6). 
Hungary may expect 38 million euros between 2000–2006. This sum is 
given only in case Hungary has adequately prepared for the reception. (This 
sum may even double if Hungary is better prepared for the reception and utili-
sation of these funds than the other candidates.) The criteria of the distribution 
of funds among candidates is as follows: 
−  The share of agricultural population from the total 
−  The share of agricultural land from the total 
−  The GDP per head on calculated purchasing power parity 
−  The situation in the given country 
Table 6 
The distribution of SAPARD funds 
Country 
Value in 1999 
(euro) 
Bulgaria 
52 124 000 
31 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Czech Republic 
22 063 000 
Estonia 
12 137 000 
Poland 
168 683 000 
Latvia 
21 848 000 
Lithuania 
29 829 000 
Hungary 
38 054 000 
Romania 
150 636 000 
Slovakia 
18 289 000 
Slovenia 
6 338 000 
Total 
520 000 000 
Source: Newsletter, 14 August 1999 EC DG VI 
 
The planning and tendering system of SAPARD follows the system of 
Structural Funds. Payments, monitoring and evaluations follow the rules of 
EAGGF. 
−  To win the grants national plans of agriculture and rural development 
should be prepared and approved by the European Committee 
−  The preparation, execution and monitoring of programmes should meet 
the concrete requirements of the Structural Funds and should contribute to 
the transfer of the legal regulations of EU (acquis communautaire) with 
special regard to the Common Agricultural Policy. 
−  Co-finance is a must. The Hungarian government allocates a separate fund 
for financial assistance to national SAPARD programmes from the 
Hungarian side 
−  The approval and coordination system match with the regional pro-
gramme of EU member countries 
−  The utilisation of grants should undergo a preliminary and interim analy-
sis, a continuous monitoring and a subsequent evaluation process for the 
efficiency assessment of programmes and to see how the programmes 
have been realised. 
−  EU conform payment agencies should be established in candidate coun-
tries 
−  Candidate countries should submit an annual report to the European 
Commission until the end of the sixth month of the following year 
 
The county level (NUTS III) and the regional level (NUTS II) sub-pro-
grammes of the Hungarian National Plan for the SAPARD programme were 
prepared by the middle of 1999 and they were followed by the preparation of 
the National Plan for SAPARD programme. Hungary’s National Plan for 
SAPARD was submitted to the EU Brussels Office on 29 December 1999. The 
32   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Programme was proposed for approval by the STAR Committee, a committee 
for the evaluation of SAPARD proposals, on 13 September 2000. 
With Hungary’s SAPARD programme the proposals of five other countries 
(Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Poland, Latvia and Slovenia) were approved. 
Although in Hungary the institutional system of SAPARD has already been 
established no agreements have been made on its accreditation and seven-year 
financial settlement. The agreements are scheduled for the first months of year 
2001. 
As only short time was available for the preparation of the national Plan for 
the SAPARD programme there was no time for building a bottom to top scheme 
starting from micro regional (NUTS IV) level ending with national level. Micro 
regional plans for the SAPARD programmes were prepared at a later time than 
the national one. The call for the preparation of micro regional projects was 
announced in April 1999. 192 local government associations or micro regions 
submitted their proposals. Because of the large number of applicants the 
Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development approved all proposals. The 
proposals were categorised into ‘A’ ‘B’ or ‘C’ groups depending on their 
quality. The timing of their analytical, strategic and operative programmes was 
different. 
Hungary’s SAPARD Programme was prepared on the basis of tasks included 
in the SAPARD Decree (1268/99/EC). The tasks proposed by the Brussels 
administration were as follows: 
1.  Investments into agricultural holdings 
2.  Improving the processing and selling of agricultural and fishery 
products 
3.  Quality check, improving the conditions of animal and plant health 
checking system to increase food quality and to protect the consumer 
4.  Environment and landscape friendly agricultural production 
5.  Development and diversification of alternative business economies 
6.  Launching a temporary retirement programme for agricultural farmers 
and providing farm management services for them 
7.  Establishment of farmers’ groups 
8.  Village modernisation and regeneration, the preservation of the material 
and intellectual heritage of rural areas 
9.  Land value increase and the modernisation of the agricultural land 
system (land property resizing) 
10. The establishment and modernisation of the land property 
administration system 
11.  Improvement of professional training 
12.  Modernisation of rural infrastructure 
13.  Modernisation of the agricultural water management system 
33 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
14.  Forestry, including forest planting, investment into private forest farms, 
the processing of forestry products 
15.  Consulting, information on tasks included in this decree, preparation of 
studies concerning the preparation and monitoring of this programme, 
informing the public on events 
On the basis of this list the 2349/1999 (XII.21.) Government Decree 
approved the following list of tasks to be supported by the SAPARD 
Programme in Hungary. 
 
Hungary’s Rural Development Programme SAPARD 
(The share of financial assistance to be given at the beginning 
and at the end of programme) 
 
Agricultural tasks  
1.   Investments into agricultural holdings 
2.  Improvement of the processing and marketing of agricultural and fish-
ery products (26–7.4%) 
3.  Improvement of vocational training (1.8–2.7%) 
4.  Agri-environment measures (3.7–7.4%) 
5.  Setting up producer groups (7.3–7.3%) 
Rural development tasks 
6.   Renovation of villages (7.5–12%) 
7.  . Economic activities providing alternative income (15–17%) 
8.   Improvement of rural infrastructure (11–15.5%) 
9.   Assistance to projects contributing to the operation of this programme 
(2–2%) 
According to this concept, the development of agriculture will have a prior-
ity in the first few years of the seven-year programming period but in the sec-
ond half rural development projects will receive higher grants.  
Agricultural project proposals should be submitted to the county offices of 
the Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development while rural development 
proposals should be submitted to the regional offices of SAPARD.  
No geographical limits are to be set up against agricultural project proposals 
if the criteria of tender invitation are met but rural development proposals are 
accepted only from typically rural areas. They are in our case settlements with a 
population density below 120 per square kilometres. 
The community support of SAPARD may not exceed 50 per cent in case of 
profit-oriented investments and may not exceed 75 per cent in case of non-profit 
projects. In both cases 75 per cent of grants is funded from the EU and 25 per 
34   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
cent is funded from the Hungarian budget. The Ministry of Agriculture and 
Rural Development allocated 3.5 billion HUF for the funding of SAPARD 
projects from the Hungarian side. Although the call for SAPARD Programme 
was not announced by the European Union at that time, this 3.5 billion HUF 
was available through a tendering system for rural development investment 
projects (until 15 September 2000). 
As SAPARD is a decentralised fund, the EU authorises candidate countries 
to use it by their own request but requires their supervision over the utilisation 
of grants. Brussels does only a final supervision. If it comes out that the 
evaluation of project proposals was not satisfactory the money received should 
be sent back to Brussels. If significant disorders are detected Brussels may stop 
funding the whole project. 
Through SAPARD Brussels is going to prepare the ten preaccession coun-
tries for the adaptation of the Community’s legal and funding system. This will 
enable them for integration after accession. However, there are four problems 
that may hinder the realisation of the objectives of SAPARD programme. They 
are as follows: 
1.  The annual sum of 520 million euros (38 million for Hungary) is very 
low. To illustrate this, in 2000 40920 million euros was given to 8 million 
farmers in the 15 EU member states (Table 7) 
2.  Due to the lack of own resources, SAPARD assistance will be given to 
wealthy farmers instead of the handicapped. It is the poorest that this 
money should be given to use for education, community development 
and some small-scale investment to start their own business. 
3. SAPARD is mostly characterised by those things that have been ex-
cluded. They are those three tasks that are included in the rural develop-
ment chapter of Common Agricultural Policy, such as: 
– Quality product marketing 
– Services for rural economy and society 
– Assistance to rural tourism and handicraft activities 
These tasks may trigger endogenous local development. They are essen-
tial for the establishment and development of agriculture based rural 
economy. 
4.  SAPARD gives financial assistance to projects instead of programmes. 
Small independent projects will not generate overall development 
through a whole region. It would have been more reasonable if the Euro-
pean Union’s Council had stipulated in the 1268/1999 EK SAPARD De-
cree that it is projects that should be funded. They should be such projects 
that ignite overall regional development. 
 
 
35 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
11  Rural development in Hungary after the EU 
accession 
In 1999 on the Berlin Summit of EC it seemed that Hungary would join the EU 
in 2002. Now it is obvious that this will not happen and even the exact date of 
the accession of the first Central European countries is still unknown. There are 
greater uncertainties about the European union’s intention with the agricultural 
farmers of the new countries. Can they expect the same grants with those who 
are in countries joined to the EU at an earlier time? Or should they do with 
lower grants? The second question is so important that may almost decide the 
first one. The European Union seems to be uncertain to decide the exact date of 
the next enlargement because they do not intend to give the same grants to the 
farmers of the new countries with those being in the fifteen member states. 
Hungary’s present agricultural policy is very liberal compared to the policy 
of the EU. Foreign citizens are not allowed to purchase agricultural land but 
there are no restrictions for them to leasing, farming or working on Hungarian 
land. Several German, Austrian and other citizens of the European Union oper-
ate and manage farms on several thousand hectares in Hungary. On the EU side 
a new regulation came into force on 1st July 2000 on the operation of private 
business in the EU for citizens of associated countries. This regulation had the 
same text for all associated members recorded in the agreement of associated 
membership in 1991. 
The agreement stipulates that from the middle of 2000 citizens coming from 
associated countries have unlimited rights to establish a private business 
through the European Union. Three businesses are excluded from this right. No 
citizens from the countries of associated membership may work as lawyers, 
bankers or farmers. They have no right either for land purchasing or leasing. 
(The reason is obvious: as farming in the European Union automatically re-
ceives serious grants, citizens from other countries are not welcome to receive 
such grants.) In these circumstances the European Union’s demand against 
Hungary and other East European countries for the liberalisation of land pur-
chase seems at least to be hypocritical. If someone says you may buy land but 
first you must live here but if you want to live here you must have a business 
license and if no business license is given for farming, this is practically a land 
purchase and land lease ban. 
After Hungary’s EU accession rural development in Hungary will primarily 
depend on agricultural development. 
The EU budget for 2000–2006 offers limited opportunities for the integra-
tion of Hungarian rural development into the funding system of the EU (Table 
7).
 The reason for that is that in the budget approved in Berlin in March 1999 
two items were separated: 
36   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
−  Support for the fifteen members 
−  Support for the preparation of accession countries and for the Union’s 
enlargement 
In year 2000 45.6 per cent of the total budget will be spent on agriculture. In 
the following six years of the programming period this will increase to 49.1 per 
cent (Table 7). 
Article 7 of the Berlin budget is about preaccession funds. These funds go up 
to 3.4 per cent of the total EU budget covering three areas: 
1. Agriculture (520 million euro annually) 
2. Structural funds of preaccession (1040 million euros annually) 
3. PHARE (candidate countries) (1560 million euros annually) 
These sums will be the same during the seven-year programming period. 
How much really is the annual sum of 520 million euros (38 million for Hun-
gary)? 
The total grant that all the candidates receive annually for the modernisation 
of their rural and agricultural system is only a little more than half of the grants 
Austria receives alone from the rural development funds of Common Agricul-
tural Policy. Beyond these grants Austria receives direct payments and other 
agricultural grants from the EU. 
From 2002 the EU budget will be extended by a separate fund under the title 
of preaccession funds to cover the enlargement costs. It is a sum of 45 billion 
euros (for the period between 2002–2006). It is not clear yet how many coun-
tries this budget will refer to. Three countries will surely be in the first round 
but also may be that all the six countries of the Luxembourg group (the Czech 
Republic, Poland, Hungary, Estonia, Slovenia and Cyprus) will receive this 
fund. Hungary is obviously in the first group of accession candidates. The en-
largement funds include two headings: 
−  Agriculture 
−  ther expenses. 
37 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Table 7 
The financial budget of the fifteen member countries for the period 2001–2006 
(Million Euro on year 1999 value, financial commitments) 
 
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 
1. AGRICULTURE 
40 920  42 800  43 900
43 770
42 760
41 930
41 660
Common Agricultural Policy  36 620  38 480  39 570
39 430
38 410
37 570
37 290
(without rural development)  
Rural development with 
4 300 
4 320 
4 330
4 340
4 350
4 360
4 370
relevant tasks 
2. STRUCTURAL POLICY 
32 045  31 455   30865
30 285
29 595
29 595
29 170
Structural Funds 
29430  28 840  28 250
27 670
27 080
27 080
26 660
Cohesion Fund 
2615 
2 615 
2 615
2 615
2 515
2 515
2 510
3. INTERNAL POLICIES 
5 900 
5 950 
6 000
6 050
6 100
6 150
6 200
4. EXTERNAL ACTIONS 
4 550 
4 560 
4 570
4 580
4 590
4 600
4 610
5. ADMINISTRATION 
4 560 
4 600 
4 700
4 800
4 900
5 000
5 100
6. RESERVES 
900 900 650
400
400
400
400
Monetary 
reserves 
500 500 250
0
0
0
0
Emergency 
reserves 
200 200 200
200
200
200
200
Guarantee 
reserves 
200 200 200
200
200
200
200
7. PREACCESSION FUNDS 
3120 
3 120 
3 120
3120
3 120
3 120
3 120
Agriculture 
520 520 520
520
520
520
520
Preaccession structural funds 
1040 
1 040 
1 040
1 040
1 040
1 040
1 040
PHARE (candidate countries) 
1560 
1 560 
1 560
1 560
0 560
1 560
1 560
TOTAL COMMITMENT 
91 995  93 385  93 805
93 005
91 465
90 795
90 260
TOTAL PAYMENT 
85 590  91 070  94 130
94 740
91 720
89 910
89 310
Total payment in the 
1.13 1.12 1.13
1.11
1.05
1.00
0.97
percentage of the GNP of the 
15 members 
ENLARGEMENT SUMS 
 
 
4 140
6 710
8 890
11 440
14 220
(payments) 
Agriculture 
 
 
1600
2 030
2 450
2 930
3 400
Other expenses 
 
 
2 540
4 680
6 640
8 510
10 820
TOTAL PAYMENT 
89 590  91 070  98 270 101 450 100 610 101 350 103 530
MAXIMUM 
Total payment maximum in 
1.13 1.12 1.18
1.19
1.15
1.13
1.13
the percentage of the GNP of 
the 15 members 
Available sum after payments 

0.14 0.15 0.09
0.08
0.12
0.14
0.14
in the percentage of the GNP 
of the 15 members 
Own resource maximum in 

1.27 1.27 1.27
1.27
1.27
1.27
1.27
the percentage of the GNP of 
the 15 members 

Source: Presidency Conclusions, Berlin, European Council, 24–25 March 1999, Table A, p. 26. 
38   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
1.6 billion euros are allocated for agricultural and 2.5 billion euros are allo-
cated to cover other expenses in year 2002 (This is 6.6 per cent of the EU 
budget in year 2002). These sums gradually increase in the next four years. 12 
million euro will be spent for agriculture and 33 billion Euro for other costs in 
the next five years. From the enlargement funds the share of agriculture is 27 
per cent while other costs take 73 per cent of the budget. At the same time 
Common Agricultural Policy (without rural development) will receive 40.1 per 
cent of payments within the 15 member states. This means that at the present 
situation – from the point of agricultural grants – the EU is not going to treat 
associated countries as equal partners.
 It would be reasonable to change this 
situation – for example by the Hungarian delegation during the EU accession 
talks – otherwise the European Union will have two categories of farmers: first 
class and second class. This does not fit into the European Union’s basic prin-
ciples. 
 
 
12 Summary 
In Hungary the disintegration of the traditional peasant society took place in a 
very short time. Within twenty years (1950–1970) the rate of agricultural farm-
ers decreased from 50 per cent to 25 per cent. This process was accelerated by 
the Soviet type collectivisation. Nevertheless, Hungarian agriculture was suc-
cessful in the socialist era. The country’s geographic soil and climatic condi-
tions turned Hungary a major agricultural producer among CMEA countries. 
Letting farmers maintain their private farms if wanted was the greatest merit of 
Hungarian socialist agricultural policy. Several farmers used this opportunity. 
Part-time farming needed no (or very small) investment but heavy work. Farm-
ers were told what and how should be produced and the goods the made were 
purchased. The income they earned created a feeling of social security, which 
was lost after the political transformation. With the loss of income farmers 
completely lost their self-reliance. They could do nothing but sell or lease their 
land. Only a small group having qualifications, good contacts and some venture 
capital enabling them to start their own business could turn to be the winners of 
privatisation. The rate of agricultural farmers has dropped by fifty per cent, 
which increased unemployment because the majority of rural workers were 
employed and had no private business. Rural development should have the 
objective of teaching villagers to be and think as a businessman.  
In the last ten years a large migration started to rural areas. Both the urban 
middle class and the urban poor escaped to villages. At the same time a large 
number of village cottages was purchased by foreigners in recreational areas, 
and in quiet out of world places.  
39 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
The efforts Hungarian governments have done so far for rural development 
since the political transformation were insufficient for triggering economic 
development. The growth of disparities made the majority of Hungarian villages 
feel as losers. The improvement of this situation is the major task of Hungarian 
agricultural and rural policy. It is very important that Hungarian villages were 
able to join the European Union as winners in a situation when the shocks of 
political transformation are still alive. 
 
 
 
 
 

40   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
References 
Agricultural situation and prospects in Central and Eastern European Countries: 
Hungary/European Commission. – Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of 
the European Communities, 1998. p. 104. ( European Union Agricultural and Rural 
Development 
Andorka, R. 1996: Közösségi és paraszti társadalom hátrányos helyzete (The 
handicapped situation of community and peasant society). – Gazdálkodás. 1. pp. 3–
15. 
A TANÁCS 1999. június 21-i 1268/99/EK rendelete a csatlakozni szándékozó közép- 
és kelet-európai országok előcsatlakozási mezőgazdasági és vidékfejlesztési 
intézkedéseinek közösségi támogatásáról az előcsatlakozási időszakban (SAPARD) 
CEC 21 June 1999 No 1268/99/EC Counsil Regulation on Community Support for 
Pre-Accession Measures for Agriculture and Rural Development (SAPARD) in the 
Applicant Countries of Central and Eastern Europe in the Pre-Accession Period. 
Bódi, F.–Bőhm, A. 2000: Sikeres helyi társadalmak Magyarországon.  (Successful 
Local Societies in Hungary). Budapest. Agroinform Kiadóház. (Vidékfejlesztők 
Kiskönyvtára). 
The Common Agricultural Policy 2000:  European Communities, 1999 Review. 
The Cork Declaration – A Living Countryside Cork. The European Conference on 
Rural Development. Írország. 1996. November 7–9. 
Csáki, Cs. 1997: Nemzetközi Agrárpiaci Kilátások (Prospects for the International 
Agricultural Market). Budapest. ACDI VOCA. 
Csatári, B. 1999: A kedvezményezett kistérségek besorolásának felülvizsgálata. (A 
Revision on the Categorisation of Beneficiary Microregions) Kecskemét, MTA 
RKK Alföldi Tudományos Intézet. 
Dorgai, L.–Hinora, F. 1999: Magyarország vidékfejlesztési koncepciója. (Rural 
Development Concept for Hungary). Budapest, Földművelésügyi Minisztérium, p. 
27. (Manuscript). 
Dorgai, L.–Miskó, K. 1999: A vidékfejlesztés finanszírozása az Európai Unióban. 
(Rural Development Finance in the European Union)  Budapest, AKII. 12. sz. 
Enyedi, Gy. 1980: Falvaink sorsa (The Fortune of Our Villages). Budapest, Gyorsuló 
idő. 
Fehér, A.–Dorgai, L. 1998: A vidék eltartóképességének stabilizálása, regionális 
összefüggései (The Stabilisation and Regional Interrelations of Rural Job 
Potentials). Budapest, MTA Agrártudományok Osztálya. 
Fertő, I. 2000: A Magyar agrárkereskedelem az Európai Unióval a társulási szerződés 
után (Hungarian Agricultural Trade with the European Union after the Agreement 
on Associated Membership). – Közgazdasági Szemle. Július/augusztus. pp. 585–
595. 
G. Fekete, É. 1998: Bevezetés az alulról vezényelt (bottom up) vidékfejlesztés 
elméletébe és módszertanába (An Introduction into the Theory and Methodology of 
Bottom-Up Rural Development Scheme).
 Szolnok, Kereskedelmi és Gazdasági 
Főiskola. (Térségfejlesztési ismeretek felsőfokon, 6. Phare-program.) 
41 

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Glatz, F. (szerk.) 1998: Az agrártermelés tudományos alapozása (A Scientific 
Foundation of Agricultural Production). Budapest, Magyar Tudományos Akadémia. 
(Magyarország az ezredfordulón. Agrárium). 
Halmai, P. (szerk.) 1995: Az Európai Unió agrárrendszere. (The Agricultural System of 
the European Union). Budapest, Mezőgazda Kiadó. 
Hantó, Zs. (szerk.) 1999: Magyar falvak a szocializmus után (Hungarian Villages after 
Socialism)  Szolnok, Kereskedelmi és Gazdasági Főiskola. (Térségfejlesztési 
ismeretek felsőfokon, 8. Phare-Program). 
Harza, L.–Tanka, E. 1999: A vidékfejlesztés megújuló intézményi háttere (The 
Renewal of the Institutional Background of Rural Development). Budapest, AKII. 3. 
sz. 
Hungary 2000. Regular Report from the Commission on Hungary’s Progress Towards 
Accession 8 November 2000. Internet. 
Kopátsy, S. 1996: Az elfelejtett falu. (Village Out of Memory) C.E.T. 2. 
Kovács, K.–Bihari, Zs. 2000: Concepts, Policies, Programmes and Institutions of Rural 
Development in Hungary. Budapest. Budapest Department of CRS HAS. 
(Manuscript). 
Kovács, T. (ed.) 1995: A mezőgazdaságtól a vidékfejlesztésig. III. Falukonferencia. 
(From Agriculture to Rural Developmen. 3rd Village Conference). Pécs, MTA 
Regionális Kutatások Központja. 
Kovács, T. (ed.) 1997: A fenntartható mezőgazdaságtól a vidékfejlesztésig. IV. 
Falukonferencia (From Sustainable Agriculture to Rural Development. 4th Village 
Conference). 
Pécs, MTA Regionális Kutatások Központja. 
Kovács, T. (ed.) 2000: Integrált vidékfejlesztés. V. Falukonferencia. (Integrated Rural 
Development. 5th Village Conference). Pécs, MTA Regionális Kutatások Központja. 
Kovács, T. 1998: Mi tekinthető vidéknek? (What is regarded as rural?) – Gazdálkodás 
5. pp. 39–48. 
Kovács T. 1998: The situation of rural areas in the Mid–1990’s. Eastern European 
Countryside, 4. Warsaw, pp. 75–81. 
Kovács, T. 2000: Integrált vidékfejlesztés. (Integrated rural development) – A Falu
Nyár. pp. 33–38. 
Kovács, T. 2000: Vidék, vidékfejlesztés, vidékpolitika (Rural areas, rural development, 
rural policy) – Gazdálkodás, 3. Budapest, pp. 11–20. 
Magyarország mezőgazdasága a 2000. évben – területi adatok. (Hungarian Agriculture 
in Year 2000 – regional data) Budapest, KSH. 
Newsletter. 14 August 1999. EC DG VI. 
Pálné Kovács, I. 1997: Merre halad a magyar vidék? (Whither Hungarian Rural?). –  
Társadalmi Szemle. 12. pp. 3–15. 
Pócs, Gy. (ed.) 1999: Vidékfejlesztés, vidékpolitika. Cikkek, tanulmányok. Válogatás ‘A 
Falu’ című folyóiratban 1996–1999 között megjelent tanulmányokból. (Rural 
Development, Rural Policy. Selected Articles and Papers from the 1996–1999 
Issues of ‘The Village’ Hungarian Journal).
 Budapest, Agroinform Kiadóház. 
Sarudi, Cs. 2000: Regionális politika és vidékfejlesztés. (Regional Policy and Rural 
Development) Kaposvár. Kaposvári Egyetem. (Egyetemi jegyzet). 
Tanka, E. 2000: Európai integráció és magyar földpolitika. (European integration and 
Hungarian land policy). – Valóság, 5. pp. 15–37. 
42   

Kovács, Teréz : Rural Development in Hungary. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 2001. 43. p. 
 
Discussion Papers, No. 34.
Tóth, E. 1998: A foglalkoztatás térségi feszültségei. (The Regional Problems of 
Employment) Budapest, AKII, 8. sz. 
Tönnies, F. 1983: Közösség, és társadalom (Community and Society). Budapest, 
Gondolat Kiadó. 
Vincze, M. 2000: Régió- és vidékfejlesztésElmélet és gyakorlat (Regional and Rural 
Development. Theory and Practice). Cluj. Presa Universitara Clujeana. 
2349/1999. (XII. 21.) Kormányhatározat a SAPARD-Program keretében nyújtott kö-
zösségi agrár- és vidékfejlesztési támogatások igénybevétele érdekében tett intézke-
désekről, az intézményi hatter megteremtéséről (2349/1999. (XII. 21.) Government 
Decree on the Tasks and Institutional Background of Community Support for Agri-
cultural and Rural Development within the SAPARD Programme). 
43