Discussion Papers 1998. No. 21. 
Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities
 
CENTRE FOR REGIONAL STUDIES 
OF HUNGARIAN ACADEMY OF SCIENCES 
 
 
 

DISCUSSION PAPERS 
 
No. 21 
Transformation in Central 
European Postsocialist Cities  
by 
ENYEDI, György 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

Series editor 
HRUBI, László 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

Pécs 
1998 
 

Discussion Papers 1998. No. 21. 
Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities
 
 
 
 
Publishing of this paper is supported by 
Strategic Task Force for European Integration 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
ISSN 0238–2008 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
© 1998 by Centre for Regional Studies of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences 
 
Technical editor: Hrubi, László 
Typeset by Centre for Regional Studies of HAS 
Printed in Hungary by Sümegi Nyomdaipari, Kereskedelmi és Szolgáltató Kft., Pécs 
 

Discussion Papers 1998. No. 21. 
Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities
 
 
CONTENTS 
Introduction  /5 
Characteristics of Urbanisation in 
the State Socialist System  /8 
Urban Aspects of the Transition  /17 
New Integration of the Settlement System, 
Growing Social Discrepancies  /17 
Transformation of the Urban Economy  /20 
Establishment of Local Governments  /25 
Evolution of the Real Estate Market  /30 
Transformation of Urban Society  /33 
Transformation of the Built Environment  /36 
International Relations and Participation in the 
International Competition of Cities  /37 
Conclusion  /39 
Notes  /43 
References  /44 
 
 




Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
Introduction 
 
Cities have traditionally been the agents and co-ordinators, as well as the 
subjects of the societal changes that have effected their transformation. An 
analysis of urban transformation may thus contribute to a more fundamental 
understanding of societal changes. However, few of the countless studies on 
the postcommunist transition discuss the development of cities. Although 
there has been considerable attention given to selected topics – e.g. local 
government, privatisation of housing, urban development in Budapest, Pra-
gue and Warsaw –, comprehensive and authoritative studies are lacking. 
The present work aims to provide precisely such a comprehensive descrip-
tion of urban transition. 
In what follows, an attempt will be made to supply answers to two prin-
cipal questions: 
1) What have been the main characteristics of the transition? 
2) What position does the Central European urban network occupy in the 
European urban network as a whole? 
It is necessary to explain a few underlying assumptions before going on 
to tackle the above questions. 
1) What will be referred to in the following as postcommunist Central 
Europe is deemed to consist the Czech Republic, Poland, Hungary, 
Slovakia, and Slovenia. This is admittedly a rather limited definition, 
but is not intended to have any political implications. It is simply that 
comparable findings of research programmes are only available from 
these countries. 
2) It can be argued that transition in Central and Eastern Europe consti-
tutes only a part of a sweeping social and economic change through-
out the world. Postcommunist transition may have a significant num-
ber of unique characteristics, but it cannot be said to be the only tran-
sition currently taking place; nor can it be understood without refer-
ence to others. Postcommunist changes are often compared to Western 
European conditions described as if they were static and fixed. This 
approach ignores, however, the simple fact that everything is ‘in flux’ 
in Western Europe as well. 
 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
‘Transition’ can be defined as a particularly significant stage of societal 
development in which more and more external and/or internal difficulties 
hinder the reproduction of the social and economic environment that forms 
the basis of society. New economic and social conditions emerge to become 
generally dominant in due course. Whether rapidly or slowly, violently or 
peacefully, these new conditions determine how the new system of society 
will look. 
These periods of transition, by no means brief, represent great epochs of 
human history. Godelier holds the view that today’s global transition signi-
fies the last phase in the universalisation of capitalism. The economic system 
engendered by the capitalist mode of production is now becoming dominant 
over all non-capitalist ways of organising production and exchanging goods 
(Godelier, 1987). In the second half of the last century, the ascendancy of 
the capitalist mode of production was limited to the North Atlantic region. 
This region, being the first to undergo this transformation, also became the 
pivot of the world economy. Transformation (i.e. the transition from feudal-
ism to capitalism) first began to spread from the centre to the periphery 
through existing trade relations; the periphery including Mediterranean 
Europe as well as Central Europe. At the same time, due to its colonisation 
or at least complete economic subjugation by the centre, social and economic 
conditions on the second periphery have scarcely been affected until the re-
cent past. As a result of abundant state support and American influence, the 
1970s saw, however, the growing dominance of the capitalist system of pro-
duction also on the periphery of the developing world. 
The advance of capitalism on the periphery has also changed the status of 
the centre. It has lost many of its former advantages in production, since 
even sectors requiring considerable expertise have been moved to the pe-
riphery where qualified labour is cheaper, more willing to co-operate with 
employers and does not demand state welfare. Europe’s relative decline has 
been especially conspicuous (the giant domestic market of North America 
mitigates the negative impact of falling competitiveness). The slowing down 
of economic growth has been dramatic and high unemployment rates have 
become permanent. 
 


Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
Systemic transformation in Central Europe has become a part of this 
global transition, but in a peculiar way. A few decades back, the semi-peri-
pheries of Central and Eastern Europe chose to run against the current, re-
jecting the course of development dictated by the centre. Now these regions 
are voluntarily giving up their opposition. At the same time, the old centre 
they would like to join seems itself to be disintegrating. One is obliged to 
confess, however, that nobody knows exactly where these countries are 
heading and what exactly is happening to them. Social sciences have yet to 
come up with comprehensive explanations. 
It can be concluded, therefore, that a combination of various kinds of 
transformation is responsible for the unique features of transition in Central 
and Eastern Europe. Obviously, one of these transformations has been 
brought about by the dissolution of state-planned economies and the one-
party system and the subsequent emergence of the market economy and po-
litical democracy. The second type of transformation is induced by the transi-
tion from the industrial city to a service-providing and information-
concentrating city. Thirdly, one also has to consider the impact of global 
transformation, for it is clear that the development of the postsocialist urban 
network is not only influenced by European trends but also by processes of 
an increasingly integrated world economy. It seems that these global proc-
esses are leading to a new phase of urban growth. This phase is marked by 
the fact that after two decades of de-urbanisation, economic growth, and es-
pecially the control of the economy and outstanding achievements in the 
fields of culture and science, once again become increasingly associated 
with large cities. Given the proliferation of novel features, it is difficult to 
assess which developments will be lasting and which not. Although urban 
development has always been informed by a degree of continuity, it is diffi-
cult to say to what extent this will be the case in the future. 
Western Europe has been serving as Central Europe’s model for more 
than a thousand years. It has always been the pioneer, a self-renewing 
source of new ideas and institutions. On the other hand, Central Europe is 
an independent region in a distinctively cultural, as well as historical, sense. 
At times it may have become closer to Western Europe, at other times it 
drifted further away, but the two regions have never become one. What is at 
  7 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
stake now is whether Central Europe will be able to accomplish a union that 
has eluded it in the past in a new, integrating Europe. Some argue that it 
stands a very good chance today, even if integration cannot be realised at a 
stroke. Others are more pessimistic and in view of the rapid growth of urban 
poverty even fear the possibility of decline to third world status. In my opin-
ion, a Western European type of development cannot be ‘decreed’. I share 
Stark’s scepticism with regard to the feasibility, of artificially designed 
forms of capitalism (Stark, 1992). On the other hand I feel that the possibil-
ity of being relegated to the third world is exaggerated. In the state-planned 
economy as well as after 1989, the course of 20th-century urbanisation in 
this region has run parallel to urban development elsewhere on the Euro-
pean periphery. It is a reasonable assumption that the Central European re-
gion will form a specific subsystem of the European urban network in the 
foreseeable future. Even if economic disadvantages are reduced in this re-
gion, societal mechanisms, as well as individual values, are not likely to be-
come identical with those in Western Europe. The same is true of the Medi-
terranean urban network that has now joined the European Union. This as-
sumption also implies that I judge the Central European urban network to be 
capable of integrating into the European urban system. It should not consti-
tute a disadvantage that a degree of difference is preserved. On the contrary, 
this may even prove to be a cultural value; why should all countries be 
obliged to follow the British and American model of development? 
In the first part of this study, I will briefly summarise the characteristics 
of the urban system in state-planned economy. This will help us to clarify 
and understand the main consequences of the transition, and make it easier 
to assess the chances of European integration. In the main part (the second 
section of the study) I will analyse key factors of the transition process. Fi-
nally I will weigh the prospects of a new united European urban system in 
the third, concluding part. 
Characteristics of Urbanisation in the State Socialist System 
Experts differ considerably on the nature of urbanisation in the state-
planned economy. Some define urbanisation in the state-planned economy 
 


Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
as distinctly different from capitalist urbanisation. Despite certain formal 
similarities, they view the former as an independent model of urbanisation 
(Szelényi, 1983). I would be more inclined to agree with those who tend to 
describe industrial and postindustrial cities in terms of the same spatial 
structure, significant regional differences notwithstanding (Enyedi, 1992). 
Most of this is already history and there seems to be little point in stirring up 
old controversies once again. Nevertheless, I would like to summarise my 
view of the characteristics of urbanisation in the state socialist system (En-
yedi, 1996
). This will enable a better estimation of how much the initial 
situation of 1989 in state-planned economies really differed from that of 
other peripheral market economies in Europe at the time. It will also make it 
possible to evaluate how much closer the Central European urban system is 
to that of Western Europe as a result of the changes after 1989. 
In my opinion, 45 years of state socialism only partly account for the pe-
culiarities of Central European urbanisation. It was also very significant that 
urbanisation was considerably delayed in Central Europe (by comparison 
with Western Europe). This delay is responsible, for instance, for the fact 
that the urban network is much more loosely-knit than in Western Europe. 
In Central Europe large cities are often surrounded by underdeveloped areas 
with a low population density. A part of the urban network is constituted by 
centres that resemble enclaves that are only connected with one another by 
traffic routes (Braun, 1994). The weakness of the urban middle classes in 
this region is another consequence of delayed urbanisation and some cities 
have even preserved remnants of the feudal orders well into the 20th cen-
tury. Feudalism in Western Europe started to weaken as early as the 13th 
century, giving rise to a significant wave of mediaeval urbanisation. Central 
Europe only experienced the same trends some five hundred years later. Ur-
banisation in Central Europe can only partly be attributed to organic devel-
opment. Rather it was to a great extent generated by state intervention and 
modernisation initiated ‘from above’. In this respect, it resembled the Rus-
sian rather than the western type of urban development. 
The transition from a rural society to an urban society has also been de-
layed. The industrial revolution really got under way in the 1870s, but never 
  9 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
completely came to fruition, and was finally halted after the First World 
War. The majority of the population still lived in the countryside in most of 
the Central European region in the 1950s. The ratio of rural population in 
Hungary was 60%, in Poland 65% and the same in Slovakia. By comparison 
with Western Europe, the growth of urban population has been much quicker 
since the 1950s. The urban network has significantly expanded as well. The 
number of cities with a population of more than 50,000 has tripled in these 
countries. By contrast, the rate of growth was only 50% in Czechoslovakia, 
which figure is identical with that in Austria and Germany. This indicates 
that the urban network of Czechoslovakia differs from that of other post-
communist countries in a number of ways. The density of Czechoslovakia’s 
small town network already resembled that of neighbouring German areas at 
the beginning of the communist regime, whereas the growth of the small 
town network in the eastern part of Central Europe only started to gather 
momentum in the 1970s (Enyedi, 1992). Despite the fact that the develop-
ment of the Czech urban network was also slower, this delay did not cause 
structural distortions. The development of the middle classes, the evolution 
of an industrial society and the functioning of the urban network have all 
been closer to that of the Austro-German part of Central Europe. By con-
trast, delayed development in the eastern part of Central Europe has resulted 
in the fact that industrialisation and transition to an urban society have only 
taken place in the state-planned economy and thus displayed typically east-
ern characteristics. In other words, the communist regime has interrupted a 
vigorous urban development in Czechoslovakia (coupled with the deporta-
tion of 3.5 million Czechoslovakian citizens of German origin in 1945–
1946, the majority of whom were town-dwellers), while in other parts of the 
region the first stage of modern urbanisation has only been completed in the 
context of a state-planned economy. It is yet to be seen whether this dis-
crepancy will also influence the manner and pace of the integration of na-
tional urban networks. Some of the initial advantages of the Czech urban 
network may be offset by a much more dynamic growth of the middle classes 
in Poland and Hungary after 1968. 
It must be noted that in spite of this delay, spatial forms of urban devel-
opment have in the main followed the Western European model. In no way 
 
10 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
can they be compared to those in developing countries. Such ‘western’ fea-
tures include the ageing of urban population, the slowing down of the 
growth of metropolitan population (or in Budapest’s case, even the begin-
ning of its decrease), the disappearance of families in which more than one 
generation lived together, the depopulation of the inner cities and the social 
erosion of central residential districts. I would in fact argue that the Central 
European urban network very strongly resembled that of the western part of 
Central Europe in 1989.1
These similarities are explained by the following factors: 
1) They reflect general laws governing the spatial development of ur-
banisation after the industrial revolution. Industrialisation has neces-
sarily led to the same spatial consequences everywhere, such as mi-
gration from villages to cities, urban concentration of the population, 
suburbanisation, extension of the urban network, integration of vil-
lages into urban agglomerations. 
2) Following the example of the Soviet Union, state-planned urban de-
velopment was combined with ideological aims at the beginning of the 
communist period. It has sought to create the ideal communist city in 
an egalitarian and communitarian fashion. It quickly became evident, 
however, that planning was not omnipotent. Central authorities may 
be able to modify some of the spontaneous tendencies of urbanisation, 
but they cannot realise an imagined urban model in an artificial way. 
Consequently, either the objectives of planning were pragmatically 
modified to accommodate spontaneous processes, or the slogan ‘let us 
catch up with the capitalist West’ made the application of western no-
tion of urban planning possible, at least in Hungary and Poland. What-
ever the cause, a similar course of urban development has produced 
similar problems to solve. 
3) Individuals can participate in processes of urbanisation even in a dicta-
torial political system. When moving house or building their own one, 
when deciding whether to stay or migrate, when choosing between 
educational institutions for their children, they influence the develop-
ment of their respective settlements. Since the value of urban spaces is 
  11 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
deeply rooted in common European cultural traditions, it has not sig-
nificantly changed during the communist regime. The population has 
rejected egalitarian ideology, preferring to live in better homes located 
in areas of higher social prestige. Society established an unofficial and 
highly effective mechanism, a kind of ‘second urbanisation’ in order 
to affirm its traditional values. 
Compared to its level of development in the interwar period, the Central 
European urban system more closely approximated to that of Western 
Europe in a number of significant ways by the end of the communist regime. 
The discrepancy between preindustrial cities of an overwhelmingly rural 
settlement structure and industrial and service-providing cities of a pre-
dominantly urbanised settlement structure had been significantly reduced. 
Nevertheless, in view of the specific characteristics of state-planned econo-
mies, other differences can be said to have increased. 
The impact of the system of state socialism on urbanisation can be sum-
marised as follows: 
1) In spite of its loud proclamation of collectivist slogans, the totalitarian 
system actually atomised and caused the disintegration of urban socie-
ties. Civil society was non-existent, collective leisure activities could 
only be pursued in local groups of cultural, sports and other associa-
tions organised and controlled by the party-state. The principal scene 
of socialisation was the place of work where the control and ‘education’ 
of citizens was easier than at their place of residence. The very tech-
niques of grassroots organisation of society had been forgotten. The 
social activities of the churches were strongly restrained. A thor-
oughly individualised society, distrustful even towards its own democ-
ratically-elected leaders and hardly capable of making even minor 
compromises, is now trying to reorganise itself in postcommunist cit-
ies. Urban planning, which previously ignored the interests of citizens, 
has found itself in a very difficult position. 
2) The development of the inner structure of society also took a peculiar 
course. With the introduction of the economic system of state owner-
ship, almost everybody became a state employee. The economic sys-
 
12 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
tem based on private property was abolished or at least very much 
limited. Society became increasingly proletarianised, and few mem-
bers of the old middle class preserved their status as freelancers or 
prominent intellectuals. The social elite was completely reshuffled, 
and the economic and political elite of the times before the communist 
regime was replaced by a new elite. Especially in the initial period, 
this new elite was quite uneducated, but had a strong political com-
mitment. It was recruited from party officials, managers of large state-
owned companies and top functionaries of the state administration. 
The official ideology called for the unification of society, while in fact 
economy and society became more and more heterogeneous and the 
complexity of the social structure also increased significantly. The 
distance between the haves and have-nots actually increased despite 
the fact that society continued to display some egalitarian features. 
Poverty was mitigated by full employment, the homeless were ac-
commodated in workers’ hostels, and everybody could afford basic 
foodstuffs and other essential needs. 
From the 1970s onwards, the second urban economy increasingly 
gained ground in Poland and Hungary. This not only provided a new 
source of income, but also strengthened the middle classes, holding 
out the possibility of exercising autonomous economic decisions and 
making capital accumulation possible. It was by and large tolerated 
that a parallel society of an increasingly middle-class character began 
to be established ‘behind the scenes’ of the official society. 
3) Cities preserved their overwhelmingly industrial character. The expan-
sion of the urban network was to a large extent caused by the location 
of industry in the countryside. It was not the case that dynamic com-
mercial cities attracted industry (there were few of these), but industry 
turned villages into cities. The transition from industrial city to a ser-
vice-providing city progressed slowly, although this trend was still 
more manifest here than in Eastern Europe. This can partly be attrib-
uted to a large industrial demand for labour,2 and partly to the fact that 
services were not profit-oriented and remained generally backward. 
  13 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
The state-planned economy could not move beyond the industrial city. 
In other words, it preserved a Fordist organisation of industry, even if 
this was accompanied by different social mechanisms from those in 
‘Fordist’ Western Europe. 
4) Cities had access to development funds through the redistribution of 
the central budget. Thus development did not depend on internal re-
sources, nor did the volume of available funds depend on the perform-
ance of the local economy, but merely on the ability of a particular ur-
ban settlement to represent its interests. The chief objective of urban 
policies was to influence redistributing centres. This has had a number 
of consequences. Firstly, capitals could lobby for their interests par-
ticularly well, given that in the centralised system of state socialism 
all strategic decisions, including economic decisions, were made in in-
stitutions of the party and state administration located in the capital. 
Nevertheless, the excessive growth of capitals was hindered by the 
fact that other cities, regional and large industrial centres in particular, 
also had a considerable lobbying potential. Consequently, the devel-
opment of centres in the countryside was also relatively well-
balanced. The losers in this race were clearly the villages that had 
very limited access to funds for settlement development. As a result, the 
urban/rural dichotomy, characteristic of early industrialisation, was 
preserved under the command economy. This discrepancy was only 
made even worse by the fact that infrastructural developments were 
consistently ignored.3 Infrastructural investments in transport, energy 
and housing were carried out only as long as they were vital to the 
functioning of industry. Regional infrastructural developments have 
also neglected rural areas. The rural population, amounting to 35–40% 
of the entire population, was thus placed at a serious disadvantage. 
These disadvantages have only increased in the competitive environ-
ment of market economies. 
5) State-planned economies operated as closed national economies, and 
economic, cultural and other relations over national boundaries were 
regulated by international agreements. Cities, therefore, were also her-
 
14 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
metically sealed in their respective national spaces and their sphere of 
influence was never able to transcend the country’s borders. They could 
only absorb immigrants from their respective areas and were organ-
ised into a planned hierarchy within their countries. The cities of the 
Central European region were also non-participants in the competition 
between European cities which led elsewhere to the formation of dif-
ferent specialised urban groups at various levels. 
6) Urban development in the state-planned economy also influenced the 
built environment and the urban land use in specific ways. One sees 
here another instance of the preservation of early 20th-century forms 
of spatial organisation. A good example is the peculiar course of sub-
urbanisation that conserved the semi-rural character of communes in 
the urban agglomeration and kept the number of daily commuters at 
high levels. The middle classes had not yet begun to move to the sub-
urbs, or at least this is how it looked on the surface. All large cities 
sought to devour neighbouring settlements by administrative means, 
because a large population brought benefits in the redistribution of re-
sources. One result of this, however, was that the inner suburban ring 
was moved within city boundaries. Other anachronistic features of spa-
tial organisation can be seen in the continuing prestige of downtown re-
sidential areas and the mixing of a relatively small central business 
district with retailing areas. Similarly, residential quarters merged 
with industrial areas and proletarian districts continued to exist. Time 
seemed to have stood still here. Modernisation in state socialism was 
so obsessively focused on industrialisation that it was in effect imitat-
ing a past epoch, namely that of the industrial revolution. Nevertheless, 
surviving forms of urbanisation disguised a much altered content. 
Workers did not move to the suburbs because they could not afford 
rents in downtown areas, but because they were excluded from the 
state redistribution of housing, in certain cases even having to suffer 
administrative restrictions. The central business area remained so 
small because the state-planned economy simply did not need finan-
cial institutions and other commercial services. The decline of down-
  15 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
town residential areas is another phenomenon that on the surface may 
appear to be analogous to corresponding developments in Western 
Europe. Yet these inner residential areas did not start to decline be-
cause of the exit of the middle classes and real estate speculation, as in 
Western Europe. Slums grew up rather because of physical decay and 
failure to maintain state-owned residential buildings, as well as 
through the allocation of low-quality flats to poor families with many 
children. 
State socialism has also left an indelible mark on the urban structure il-
lustrated, for example, by the fact that a considerable part of the population 
still lives in large housing estates. Such estates were also built in Western 
Europe, but they were only intended to accommodate those moving to the 
city and low-income groups of the population. Moreover they went out of 
fashion in the West more than twenty years ago. By contrast, the construc-
tion of housing estates has been the main form of housing until the recent 
past in Central Europe. 
Flats were allocated by local councils, partly according to needs, partly 
according to ‘merit’. Since these flats were not only acquired by the poor, the 
allocation of homes did not generate segregation. From the 1970s on, how-
ever, a limited form of real estate market began to develop in Poland and 
Hungary. Those in higher income brackets, especially members of the intel-
ligentsia, began to buy or build homes in residential areas with higher social 
prestige. This development was accompanied by the decline of housing es-
tates. It is interesting to note that, as already mentioned, residential segrega-
tion did not completely disappear in egalitarian societies. Its mechanism 
simply became more complicated, because market conditions were only simu-
lated, although the address of a residence still more or less implied a corre-
sponding social status. 
This was the general state of the Central European urban network at the 
beginning of the transition: in some ways similar to the Western European 
urban system, in some ways different. As I have already remarked, in my per-
ception the similarities were more fundamental and generally speaking, the 
cities of the Central European region form a part of the European urban sys-
 
16 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
tem. Changes after 1989 have made the similarities even more conspicuous. 
I would define the following aspects to be the most important elements of 
the transformation process: 
• market-oriented integration of the settlement system, leading to an in-
crease in social discrepancies; 
• transformation of the urban economy; 
• establishment of local governments; 
• evolution of the real estate market; 
• transformation of urban society; 
• transformation of the built environment; 
• establishment of international relations, participation in the interna-
tional competition of cities. 
These changes will be briefly discussed in the following section. 
Urban Aspects of the Transition 
New Integration of the Settlement System, 
Growing Social Discrepancies
 
The settlement structure formed an integral part of the centralised system of 
state administration under state socialism. Cities were organised in a hierar-
chical structure according to the level of administrative institutions located 
in them. Their place in the hierarchy was assigned by central planning, hav-
ing regard to a number of priorities. The highest priority in the period of ex-
tensive industrialisation was the presence of industry, in particular heavy 
industry. Later, the service-providing functions of a city with respect to set-
tlements in its attraction zone were also considered. The city’s share of the 
central budget depended on its position in the hierarchy. The availability of 
resources for development was determined neither by a city’s actual circum-
stances, nor by successful or unsuccessful management of its affairs, but 
merely by the city’s effective bargaining potential in the process of redistri-
bution at its own level of the hierarchy. 
  17 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
Three distinctly different levels of relationships between settlements 
emerged. The first was constituted by economic relations. Companies in a 
given settlement, whether co-operatives or state-owned, made business con-
tacts with other industrial companies or (also state-owned) domestic and in-
ternational trading companies. These connections, however, were not mar-
ket-oriented–not even in the Hungarian economy, which was closest to a 
market economy. Links between companies were either determined by cen-
tral planning or by the economic organisations of the state, which enjoyed a 
monopolistic position in the economy. At the same time, economic connec-
tions were regulated by one of the administrative centres, and neither local 
authorities nor the companies in any city could influence the direction or in-
tensity of these connections. 
The other level of relationships between settlements was represented by 
connections in public services. The latter term stood for a fairly wide range 
of services, including retail trade. Local authorities were not only tasked 
with the supervision of education and health services, but also had to attend 
to such fundamental matters as ensuring that there was enough bread in the 
shops before official holidays. The scope of public services was determined 
centrally. The centre regulated which hospital, secondary school and bank 
could be used by any individual inhabitant of a given settlement. A city’s 
sphere of influence, therefore, did not evolve on the basis of spontaneous 
connections and boundaries were fixed in a bureaucratic fashion. 
The third type of relationships between settlements was based on the 
freely exercised preferences of the population. These could only manifest 
themselves in retail trade, in the possibilities for shopping at different mar-
kets and in various leisure activities. Hungarian regional geography began 
investigating certain preferences of the population with regard to markets 
and shopping precisely because these implied the natural spheres of influ-
ence of various settlements and settlement hierarchies in the perception of 
the population.4  
The control of relationships between settlements diminished inequalities 
between the living standards of various settlements, or at least did so at any 
 
18 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
given level of settlement hierarchy. Traditional social differences between 
settlements were disguised by state paternalism. 
The transition led to the dissolution of the former network of connections 
organised by the state which has partly been replaced by market-oriented re-
lationships. The market, however, differentiates by its very nature, and thus 
latent discrepancies have been dramatically exposed. Since this has been 
coupled with a general economic recession, backwardness has meant not 
only a reduced availability of services, but also unemployment and indeed 
basic problems of subsistence for certain settlements. In the wake of the 
transition, settlements had to adapt alone to radical changes, the balancing 
and protecting role of the state having been radically curtailed. Jealous of 
their newly discovered independence, local governments, which replaced 
former councils, have been reluctant to form microregional associations 
with other settlements, even when co-operation would have been the most 
expedient way of managing the institutions providing public services (I will 
come back to the functioning of local governments later.) 
Market-oriented integration of settlements has been driven forward by 
the privatisation of state property, a quickly expanding private sector and a 
partial privatisation of public services. The possibility of turning local char-
acteristics and advantages to account has released enormous energies and 
led to a spectacular development of certain settlements. The lack of com-
petitiveness, however, has been exposed in an equally spectacular way. Dif-
ferences between settlements depend first of all on the potential of the local 
population to adapt to new circumstances, as well as on the geographical lo-
cation of the settlement (and therefore such things as its communication 
links, and vicinity to dynamic centres). This is also the reason why geographi-
cal inequalities are much greater than before. They are not only palpable at a 
regional level, since innovative centres may emerge in any part of the set-
tlement system, and even in underdeveloped areas. These centres are con-
nected to other, often remote dynamic centres through the integrative forces 
of the market, and this may weaken traditional ties between ‘the city and the 
surrounding country’, at least as far as the market sector is concerned. 
  19 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
An in-depth understanding of the new forces shaping the settlement sys-
tem is not yet within our reach. The old network of connections has disinte-
grated too rapidly, and the new is taking a long time to develop. Connective 
links, therefore, are not always effective, some of the relations between set-
tlements being either inadequately regulated or functioning in a deficient way. 
Transformation of the Urban Economy 
The prosperity of a city depends first and foremost on the local economy. 
Business decisions lay the groundwork for growing employment and deter-
mine the nature and intensity of external economic relations. Local taxes are 
also mostly contributed by the business sector. An awareness of this, how-
ever, is usually slow to strike root. Local governments are more focused on 
gaining relatively moderate amounts of governmental subsidies than on try-
ing to involve local companies in settlement development. Needless to say, 
business decisions are motivated by profit and not by settlement develop-
ment. Companies have to be made directly interested in the development of 
the city. 
The emergence of local economies signifies an enormous change when 
compared to the economy of state ownership. Production, development and 
economic relations of an industrial or services company located in a given 
city used to be decided by a remote company or by administrative centres in 
the state-planned economy.5 Only technological decisions were made locally. 
By the same token, there were no business relations between branch plants 
of state-owned companies in the same settlement, especially if they be-
longed to different company headquarters or ministries. The void left by the 
lack of official relations was filled by an elaborate web of informal personal 
connections, so that the company management was often involved in local 
government. Provided that there was a good personal relationship between 
the management and the local political leadership, companies participated in 
the financing of public services or even provided these themselves in return 
for favours. In small towns and in particular ‘new towns’, this ‘industrial pa-
ternalism’ played an important part in the provision of public services. 
 
20 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
Industry had a vital function in the economic structure of both small and 
medium-sized towns and large cities. In the absence of market conditions, 
business services were also underdeveloped in large cities, although these 
showed a concentration of company headquarters, as well as centres of edu-
cation, research and cultural life. Industry progressively moved out of large 
cities from the 1970s, but this tendency only resembled the deindustrialisa-
tion of large cities in Western Europe, which exhibited similar statistics of 
relocations. Large state-owned industry, constantly trying to attract more la-
bour and not being faced with budgetary or market constraints, was simply 
unable to find an adequate work force any more in large cities. This is why 
companies started to relocate branch plants in rural areas that had an excess 
supply of labour. This strategy was also supported by regional policy aiming 
at the reduction of regional inequalities. However, such resettlements were 
not motivated by the pursuit of higher efficiency. 
Local economies have emerged gradually, depending on what stage the 
privatisation of the economy has reached, or how far the state-owned econ-
omy has been transformed and integrated into the market economy in any 
given country. There are two alternative forms of privatisation: either state 
property is transferred into private ownership or new private enterprises are 
launched. These alternatives have been put into practice in different ways in 
each of the five Central European countries (Frydman–Rapaczynski, 1994). 
The state-owned economy has remained strongest in Slovakia and Slovenia. 
Figures suggest that private ownership is the highest in the Czech Republic, 
but this is a peculiar form of private ownership that actually disguises the 
conservation of an economic structure dominated by state ownership.6 The 
participation of foreign capital and transnational companies in privatisation 
has been the most active in Hungary. Significant amounts of domestic capi-
tal were accumulated during the fifteen years before the transition in Poland, 
Hungary and Slovenia. 
At present, urban economy in the region is constituted by the following 
elements: 
• A fully or partly state-owned economy. Despite its still existing access 
to central subsidies it is not able to adapt to market competition other 
  21 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
than by reducing the number of employees. Cities with large state-owned 
companies, which enjoyed several privileges in the state-planned econ-
omy, have experienced serious unemployment problems. 
Ownership rights of large state-owned companies are exercised by 
administrative organisations of the state or state-owned shareholding 
companies. Although the state-owned economy is still controlled cen-
trally in this way, it has been integrated into the local economy. State-
owned companies have lost a considerable share of their markets after 
the collapse of the Comecon. A part of the companies still in majority 
state ownership belong to the armaments industry. The future of these 
companies is still uncertain. State-owned companies have an important 
share in foreign markets and thus strengthen international relationships 
between settlements. At the same time, they seldom establish subcon-
tracting connections to local private economy. 
• A local, private economy. This is chiefly made up of individual entre-
preneurs and small enterprises with a handful of employees. It plays a 
very important role in the development of local economies. The sig-
nificance of this role can be attributed to the following factors: 
a) the local private economy has a direct and continuous interest in set-
tlement development; 
b) co-operational, subcontracting relations formed within the local pri-
vate economy stimulate the entire economy and expand local mar-
kets; 
c) a considerable part of the local private economy operates in the ser-
vices sector. It is more difficult for these enterprises to move to an-
other location than it is for manufacturing activities; 
d) the majority of the owners of local private economy are local resi-
dents whose personal strategies are also accommodated to local cir-
cumstances. These entrepreneurs are therefore personally interested 
in the development of their settlement. 
• A local economy in majority or exclusive foreign ownership. Several 
forms of this exist, each of which has a different impact on relation-
ships between settlements. It is worth noting, however, that a signifi-
 
22 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
cant amount of foreign direct investment (FDI) is only present in the 
Hungarian settlement network and has had a general impact only there. 
In any case, FDI has settled very selectively in all Central European 
countries. The number of settlements attracting significant amounts of 
FDI has been relatively small. 
The investments of transnational companies have had the greatest indi-
vidual impact. Settlements enjoying such investments have been rapidly 
connected to the world economy. Rapid technological developments were 
made possible through the large amounts of capital involved. These invest-
ments already contribute significantly to Czech exports and even more to 
Hungarian foreign trade. Another advantage of non-European investments is 
that these prefer to establish subcontracting networks locally, in view of the 
greater distance involved and the possibility of easier access to markets of 
the European Union. By contrast, Western European investors have been less 
willing to spend time on local subcontractors unaccustomed to punctual de-
livery and steady quality. The successful operation of a transnational invest-
ment may be the best reference for a city and could become an important 
element in its marketing policy. The settling of a transnational company is 
also an incentive to improve the general environment in the settlement and 
generates demand for a highly qualified work force. 
The presence of transnational companies is, however, not without dan-
gers. For example, they may use their massive concentration of capital to 
drive domestic companies out of the market. Products are usually developed 
in research laboratories located in the most advanced countries, and there-
fore local industrial research institutes are not required. If local advantages 
become less attractive, which usually means labour becoming more expen-
sive, they can relocate production to another country. Nevertheless, and in 
spite of these risks, their presence is one of the most important factors in the 
modernisation of the local economy. 
Small and medium-sized FDI is also present. Smaller state-owned com-
panies, which have gone bankrupt or lost much of their market value, have 
often been bought by medium-sized enterprises with moderate amounts of 
capital. It is yet to be seen whether these companies will be able to recover 
  23 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
and start to grow again. This will also depend on the expansion of national 
markets. A peculiar feature of Central European economies is the marked 
presence of small foreign family enterprises. Some of these are owned by 
returning immigrants, some by Austrian and German investors living in bor-
der regions. Investments by the latter usually remain close to the western 
borders of Central European countries. Their personal know-how is a very 
valuable source of applicable economic information. 
The transition to a local economy – characterised by mixed ownership, 
manifold spatial relations and governed largely through autonomous local 
decisions – is also accompanied by a structural transformation of the urban 
economy. The first phase of this structural transformation has proved to be 
painful since it entails a sharp fall in industrial employment. The periphery 
of the capitalist West also underwent this transformation a decade earlier. 
The size of the industrial work force decreased by 20% in Ireland between 
1979 and 1987 and by 28% between 1975 and 1985 in Spain. This can mostly 
be attributed to the decline of traditional and ineffective economic sectors. 
By contrast, the 1980s were marked by another upsurge of industrialisation, 
due for the most part to foreign investments and the relocation of industry 
from developed areas. The number of industrial employees increased by 
20% between 1985 and 1990 in Spain. Nevertheless, this work force had a 
different composition and was employed in other sectors than those hit by 
the former recession. Foreign investments have been concentrated in large 
cities: 57% of FDI has gone to Barcelona and Madrid in Spain, 82% has 
opted for Lisbon in Portugal. Given its greater demand for infrastructure and 
qualified labour, new industrialisation has been marked by a striking geo-
graphical polarisation. 
Similar tendencies can be expected in Central Europe. The grave indus-
trial recession after 1989 lasted only two or three years and the ensuing pe-
riod has been characterised by renewed industrial growth. Economic 
growth, however, has not been accompanied by improving employment fig-
ures, because competition calls for increased efficiency. The geographical 
concentration of industry is not as strong as on the periphery of Western 
Europe. Central Europe has traditionally had stronger industrial regions than 
 
24 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
Mediterranean Europe or Ireland. It is still unclear which sectors will prove 
to be the most dynamic areas of industry and this will also determine the 
new spatial location of industry. One cannot yet identify the most competi-
tive industrial sectors and respective positions in the spectrum of European 
competition are also subject to periodic change. All industrial sectors may 
offer some competitive products and technologies. High-tech industries 
have formerly been helped by their advantageous position within Comecon 
(as well as the western COCOM list). At present, however, high-tech sectors 
can only function as subcontractors of transnational companies. Owing to a 
highly-qualified and cheap work force, high-standard processing sectors 
stand a good chance of development, including the relocation of investment 
in these sectors from EU countries. This is well demonstrated by the rapid 
expansion of the car industry that has already positively affected several 
medium-sized subcontracting companies. There are examples of the com-
missioned manufacturing of cheap mass-products which may yield addi-
tional tax revenues and higher income, but has a negative effect on techno-
logical standards in industry. In the final analysis, I would forecast a partial 
reindustrialisation of urban economies. Traditional industrial centres can 
hardly avoid their decline, but structural transformation of industry in cities 
with processing industries may be successful. Central Europe could be the 
beneficiary of industry withdrawing from the most advanced regions of the 
continent. 
An important factor of the transformation of economic structure is consti-
tuted by the expansion of the services sector. The contribution of this long-
neglected sector to growing employment could be crucial. Business services 
are the most underdeveloped area, and only gradual progress can be ex-
pected, parallel with the consolidation of the market economy. One may as-
sume that high-level business services will be strongly concentrated in large 
cities. The development of international services with a macroregional sphere 
of influence can only be expected in one or two metropolises that are also 
competitive by European standards. 
  25 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
The emergence of local economies means that the development of cities 
is primarily dependent on their economic performance. The first priority of 
urban policies should be to assist in improving this performance. 
Establishment of Local Governments 
The creation of local governments in place of the council system signifies a 
landmark in urban development. Local governments are the most important 
elements in the institutional network of cities. They are the main providers 
of public services and should also represent the reactions of the local popu-
lation to governmental policies. A multiparty parliament is a necessary but 
not sufficient condition of democracy, the basic units of democracy being 
the workshops of civil organisations and local governments. Among the 
postcommunist countries, only the Czech, Polish and Hungarian laws on lo-
cal governments have guaranteed the decentralisation of power and the sub-
sidiarity of government. 
The Soviet Union imposed the council-system on its satellite states in the 
latter half of the 1940s. The essential features of this council-system were 
the following: 
1) local councils of cities were to represent the will of central authorities 
and were not supposed to articulate local interests; 
2) the election of members of local councils was a purely formal proce-
dure within the framework of the one-party system; 
3) councils at various regional levels were organised into a vertical hier-
archy; 
4) councils had virtually no financial resources of their own, their func-
tioning and development being financed through central budget redis-
tribution. 
The Hungarian and Polish council-systems had been significantly modi-
fied by the middle of the 1980s, while the Yugoslavian regional administra-
tion differed greatly from that of other communist countries from the very 
outset. The legacy of the council-system makes the functioning of local gov-
ernments more difficult. The economic weakness of urban authorities entails 
 
26 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
a continual dependence on the central budget, yet the central government 
has given very limited support to decentralisation. Having been freed from 
the yoke of the former hierarchical system, local governments themselves 
show little willingness to co-operate with each other. Expertise required for 
autonomous government is also often missing. Nevertheless, it is highly 
significant that the Central European system of local governments generally 
meets the corresponding European standards. 
Several types of local government have evolved in Europe (Bennett, 1993). 
The Central European system corresponds most of all to the French model 
in which locally elected bodies are subject to strong central control (some-
times even the mayor is nominated by the central government). New local 
governments have also adopted the principle of the separation of powers, 
consisting of a directly elected legislative (local governmental bodies) and 
an executive (usually a directly elected mayor). The council-system is easier 
left behind when the local governmental system preserves a degree of strong 
central control, although it should also be noted that centralising traditions 
date back to the times of the Austro-Hungarian Monarchy.7 With the excep-
tion of so-called free royal towns, settlements enjoyed little autonomy in the 
large and multinational Monarchy, while regional (i.e. provincial and county) 
governments were relatively powerful, acting as regional branches and re-
mote representatives of the central power. The emergence of new nation states 
in the place of the Monarchy after the First World War was not the result of 
a spontaneous development. These states represented the geo-strategic in-
terests of the victorious Western Powers with their arbitrarily drawn bor-
ders. The internal cohesion of the new states was weak, and the relative 
status of cities and administrative regional units controlling individual set-
tlements underwent change. All this has justified the survival of centralisa-
tion in successor states of the Monarchy. This is why it is difficult to com-
municate the principle of autonomous local government to the population 
and why authorities may sometimes falter in putting this principle into prac-
tice in the postcommunist countries of Central Europe. 
An important consequence of the creation of local governments is the 
strengthening of rural settlements. Among other indicators, this is demon-
  27 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
strated by the dissolution of the administrative mergers of the 1960s and 
1970s. These mergers have generally been attributed to the authoritarianism 
of a centralising communist power (although the modernisation of admini-
stration has led to administrative mergers in a number of democratic Euro-
pean countries as well). This is why the new legislation on local govern-
ments has established local governments at the level of individual settle-
ments. The number of settlements doubled in Hungary between 1989 and 
1993, grew by a third in the Czech Republic and did not change in Slovakia 
and Poland. Settlements are already quite small in Slovakia (two thirds of 
all settlements in the country have a population of less than 1000 people). 
This disintegration has been motivated by the local governments’ histori-
cally-rooted and profound distrust of regional and central governments. 
This, however, has proven to be a trap, for the small size of settlements has 
actually hindered the process of genuine decentralisation. The majority of 
them have lacked both the expertise and the financial resources to enable 
them to take up the responsibility of providing and developing public ser-
vices. ‘Sweet independence’ impedes the development of co-operation that 
could offset the handicaps of small size (e.g. joint infrastructural develop-
ments, joint running of schools). To cite one example, lack of co-operation 
has been standing in the way of a revision of the general physical plan for 
the Budapest agglomeration. 
The issue of control by regional governments over local governments has 
been debated in all of these countries. Traditionally (before 1989) settlements 
had perceived regional governments to be mere extensions of the central 
power and it is therefore not surprising that no regional local governments 
were established in 1990. However, since public services at the regional level 
are obviously indispensable, ranging from courts of second instance to spe-
cialised educational institutions, irrational and emotionally-motivated de-
centralisation has once again defeated its purpose. Centralisation has in fact 
intensified, since regional public services had to be provided by the central 
government. There are presently discussions about elected regional govern-
ments in the Czech Republic and Slovakia. Such governments were to be in-
troduced in Poland in 1993, but the general elections prevented this reform. 
 
28 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
Only in Hungary has an amendment to the law on local governments in 
1994 created some form of regional and decentralised government. Never-
theless, there are still ongoing debates about these issues in Hungary as 
well, and the present form of administration will hardly prove to be an ulti-
mate solution. 
A basic contradiction concerning the existence of local governments in 
Central Europe lies in the fact that local governments have been assigned a 
great number of duties, but have few resources at their own disposal. Local 
taxes only play a significant role in Poland (a quarter of the local budget); 
everywhere else they remain below 10% (5% in Hungary). The property of 
local governments – real estate, bonds, enterprises – could also be used as a 
source of income, but these often yield more problems than profit given that 
buildings have to be renovated, landed property cleared of environmental pol-
lution, and so on. Consequently, dependence on the central budget remains 
strong. The survival of old structures conserves old attitudes, and enjoying 
independence does not mean that local governments will not try to stay on 
good terms with governmental organisations allocating subsidies. It will be 
necessary to give unwavering support to market-oriented decentralisation by 
transferring various former public services to the market sector. This is mostly 
only hindered by the lack of local capital, although privatisation of water and 
energy utilities has occasionally provoked political resistance as well. 
It should finally be noted that local governments of capitals usually enjoy 
a unique legal position which in some cases is even regulated through spe-
cial legislation. Two specific problems present themselves with respect to 
the status of capitals. The first of these concerns the relationship between 
the capital and the local governments of individual districts. Although the 
local governments of the capital and the 23 districts have an equal status in 
Budapest, revenues from the share of personal income tax not remitted to 
the central budget are distributed by the capital’s local government among 
individual districts, a practice which gives rise to countless debates. The fact 
that welfare housing is owned by the districts makes the elaboration of a 
comprehensive housing policy for the capital impossible. In Warsaw, the 
city is governed by the local governments of the seven districts and the capi-
tal’s local government is comparably weaker than in Budapest. The other 
  29 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
problem is that co-operation between the local governments of the capital 
and its agglomeration is even more difficult than that in the case of other cit-
ies. The distinction between the capital’s government and the central govern-
ment often seems less clear-cut from the perspective of local governments in 
the agglomeration, which explains why distrust towards the capital is particu-
larly strong. This is in fact not a complete misperception, since the economic 
and political weight of capitals is extraordinary; they require larger subsidies 
for urban development and also have easier access to central funds than 
other cities. 
It may be concluded that the establishment of local governments has 
been crucially important for the democratic functioning of society as well as 
for the mobilisation of local resources and the development of programmes 
meeting local needs. Paradoxically, it is precisely the excessive striving for 
independence, the resulting fragmentation and weakness of local govern-
ments, and misgivings about co-operation that hinder a real decentralisation 
of tasks. On the other hand, it will also take time before local governments 
will be strong enough to check the traditional centralising ambitions of the 
central government. 
Evolution of the Real Estate Market 
Housing policy has a great impact on urban development. Housing is con-
trolled by a mixture of market processes and state regulations everywhere in 
Europe. Housing in the state-planned economy was completely dominated 
by state regulations, the market only having a marginal function. The build-
ing of new homes formed a part of central planning and the distribution of 
state-owned flats among applicants was also a state task (carried out by lo-
cal councils or state companies). At what rate the population of cities grew 
depended on the scope of state housing programmes. Many homes, how-
ever, were still built privately, in particular by the rural population that was 
practically excluded from state housing programmes; nevertheless the mar-
ket remained limited and controlled. A family could only own one house or 
flat plus a second home in resort areas, and even the maximum size of this 
was fixed. Building loans were lent by state banks that favoured certain 
 
30 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
forms of housing such as, for instance, those built by co-operatives. In Cen-
tral Europe, the share of flats in public ownership amounted to only 28% of 
the whole, and 49% of all homes were occupied by the owner at the time of 
the dissolution of the state-socialist system in 1990 (the rest belonged to co-
operatives and companies). There have been great differences among the 
various countries. In 1990, 77.5% of all homes, for example, were in private 
ownership in Hungary, the pioneering country of the transition to market 
economy.8 The privatisation of homes accompanying the transition has only 
had a significant impact in large cities where the value of real estate trans-
ferred into private hands was considerable. 
Positive evaluations of the socialist housing model have been few and far 
between. The contradictions underlying this model have been analysed by 
several authors. The public has perceived a serious shortage of flats, since 
tenements in public ownership were very difficult to obtain and their norma-
tive size fell short of actual demand. Hegedüs and Tosics have argued, how-
ever, that when compared to the general performance of Central European 
economy, housing conditions were actually not as poor as was widely be-
lieved. If one compares the level of housing in Central Europe to that in 
other countries with similar GDP figures (e.g. Greece, Turkey, Mexico, Chile, 
South Korea), one finds that indicators of housing conditions are generally 
favourable,9 being closer to corresponding figures in Western Europe than 
those in countries with a comparable economic output. The purchase of an 
own flat was the only case where housing conditions could be shown to be the 
worst in Central Europe, because wages were not sufficient for the costs of 
buying private flats. Hegedüs and Tosics claim that the oft cited problem of 
housing shortage is based on an unjustified comparison of Central European 
housing conditions with Western European countries, which had a six times 
greater per capita economic potential than the former. The comparison ig-
nores the fact that, due to unrealistically low rents there were practically no 
financial limits to demand in Central Europe. 
Housing in state socialism was characterised by the small average size 
and limited selection of homes. Coupled with the non-market oriented allo-
cation of houses, this resulted in the fact that there was hardly any correla-
tion between the income of a household and the size or quality of their home. 
  31 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
Due to the small number of purchasable flats, their price was extremely 
high, affordable only to households in high income brackets. The number of 
households purchasing their own homes (i.e. the ratio of average income to 
the price of an average flat) was much smaller than in either developed or 
peripheral market economies. 
The development of a real estate market first of all required the partial 
privatisation of state-owned flats. First, state-owned flats were transferred 
into the ownership of local governments. Privatisation was carried out in 
turn by local governments, which used a variety of alternative procedures. 
Privatisation had two basic forms. The property was either restored to the 
original owner at the time of nationalisation (restitution) or sold to the ten-
ant living in the flat. Restitution has not been practised at all in Hungary, 
and only in exceptional cases in Slovakia and Poland. It has only been ex-
tensively applied in Slovenia and the Czech Republic.10 Restitution has in-
volved a relatively complicated procedure and was in any case extended 
only to pieces of property used as tenements at the time of nationalisation 
and the time of reprivatisation. Serious conflicts have been generated be-
tween original owners and tenants that eventually required the regulative 
and financial intervention of governments. In Hungary, 40% of all tene-
ments were sold to the tenants, 70% in Slovenia, but everywhere else the 
figure remained negligible. Most flats in state ownership in 1990 were still 
public property at the end of 1994 in the Czech Republic and Slovakia, 
whereas their share decreased to 28% in Slovenia and 60% in Hungary. 
The first phase of the privatisation of state-owned flats was primarily 
motivated by political considerations and did not form part of a comprehen-
sive housing strategy. Hungary and Slovenia opted for predominantly mar-
ket-oriented alternatives, while the Czech Republic and Slovakia strove to 
maintain the dominance of public ownership, with Poland seeming to have 
struck a middle course. This has also influenced the building of new homes. 
State and local governmental housing programmes have been curtailed in all 
of these countries, but the participation of private enterprises in the con-
struction of new tenement buildings has only been significant in Hungary 
and Slovenia, and the average size of newly constructed homes (101 square 
 
32 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
metres and 102 square metres respectively) has also been larger here than in 
the other three countries. 
The housing sector, of course, reflects the general development of the 
Central European economy. Not only does it correlate with macroeconomic 
tendencies, it also greatly influences several other economic sectors. The 
social significance of housing conditions is also well known. The next cru-
cial step would be to develop the basic institutions of the housing market, 
including the creation of the forms and resources of a mortgage system, wel-
fare schemes, efficient maintenance and renovation. The main question in 
the ‘market-oriented’ group of countries is how the large group of private 
owners will act in the future (how will they finance the costs of maintenance 
and renovation), and to what extent and in what ways will the state (and lo-
cal governments) have to resort to restrictive measures limiting the freedom 
of the market in order to protect social equality. The basic question in the 
other three countries is whether they will follow the first group and privatise 
state-owned tenements or keep a significant non-market-oriented housing 
sector. If they do, a further question is whether they will attempt to turn it 
into an efficient non-profit sector or preserve it as a state-controlled part of 
the housing system requiring large state subsidies. 
Transformation of Urban Society 
The transition has transformed the structure, functioning and organisation of 
urban society and altered the status and spatial location of individual social 
groups in the city. The introduction of the market economy has made the 
distribution of goods more unequal; thus one of the characteristic aspects of 
the transition has been increasing social and spatial polarisation. 
As already mentioned, social differences also existed in the egalitarian 
society of state socialism. These differences, however, were associated with 
social position and not with property. Nationalisation and industrialisation 
carried out by the communist regime have not been solely responsible for 
structural changes in society in the last fifty years, the events of the Second 
World War having also played an important role in these developments. The 
  33 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
majority of the large Jewish middle class fell victim to the Holocaust, and 
later most of the town-dweller German minority of the Czech lands was also 
deported. Consequently, many members of the middle class have not only 
lost their former status, but simply disappeared from Central European cit-
ies. This has also changed the traditionally multiethnic character of these 
cities. The void left was filled by migrants from the countryside who have 
mostly increased the numbers of the urban proletariat and have found it dif-
ficult to adjust to an urban way of life that had in any case been much unset-
tled by previous changes. 
The present transformation of urban society is in part a direct conse-
quence of the transition including, for example, the emergence of the new 
elite or the presence of a large urban lower class. The other basic tendency 
underlying the transformation seems to be typical of the general laws gov-
erning the transition from an industrial city to a service-providing city. 
The new elite has few genuine newcomers. Entrepreneurs forming the 
elite of economic life, well-to-do technocrats and freelancing intellectuals 
had usually been members of the elite under state socialism, even if they 
may not have enjoyed exactly the same social status. The majority of entre-
preneurs have been recruited from the ranks of the previous political elite or 
the intelligentsia, former dissidents and technocrats; it is exceptionally rare 
to find successful entrepreneurs who have risen from the working class. The 
political elite also numbers few new members, although one might have 
formerly encountered many of the familiar faces in research institutes or lit-
erary circles. The displacement of the elite is also to be attributed to a gen-
erational change, as many young people have joined the elite who were too 
young to be active under state socialism; this is especially true of the new 
professions requiring high qualifications. Despite personal connections, the 
political, administrative and intellectual elite and the new capitalist class are 
quite clearly separated from one another. 
Węcławowicz (1992) identifies five distinct groups that make up the new 
capitalist class. The first of these is the communist nomenclature. Members 
of this group, party functionaries or former state officials of the political 
administration and economic leadership, have successfully converted their 
 
34 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
personal connections and monopoly on information, which they acquired in 
their past positions of power, into various forms of property and wealth. The 
second group consists of highly-qualified ‘self-made men and women’ 
whose enterprises have quickly become successful. The third is a group of 
experts who work for the state administration, but also run their own consul-
tancies. They can use their influence and access to important information to 
ensure the success of their private enterprises. Members of the fourth group 
have based their enterprises on intellectual innovation, as in the case of 
software laboratories and technological think-tanks owned by former re-
searchers and professors at technological colleges. Entrepreneurs of the fifth 
group already had small enterprises in the state-planned economy and now 
they are successfully expanding these under the new dispensation. A part of 
the economic activities of the new capitalist class are illegal or semi-illegal. 
The new middle classes comprise various groups that were also part of 
state socialist society. Most of these are made up of white-collar workers, 
many of whom are state employees, some having accumulated small amounts 
of capital. Upward mobility from the working class to the middle class is lim-
ited. Blue-collar workers generally lack the necessary capital, expertise and 
entrepreneurial spirit. The old comforts of state paternalism are still hoped for. 
The statistical share of the urban lower class in the population is signifi-
cant. It includes most members of a working class that has lost its former 
social status due to a dramatic fall in industrial production and industrial re-
structuring. The urban lower class has also absorbed a part of the middle 
class, such as low-paid intellectuals (e.g. primary school teachers), and elderly 
people whose pensions have lost their value. Further social decline down-
wards to the marginalised urban poor is also not unusual. This most disadvan-
taged segment of the population consists of those who have lost most from 
the transition and their appearance in large cities en masse has been the 
most shocking by-product of urban transformation. The two main groups of 
the urban poor are made up of so-called ”small pensioners” and elderly peo-
ple living on social welfare, on the one hand, and unskilled workers on the 
other. Big state-owned companies employed unskilled workers in large 
numbers, most of whom had migrated to the cities from rural regions. Most 
  35 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
of them did not have a permanent residence in the city, being lodged in 
workers’ hostels and often maintaining links to their rural background. They 
were the first losers of industrial restructuring and privatisation, having been 
laid off from economically superfluous jobs in vast numbers. Some of them 
have returned to the countryside, thus increasing rural unemployment, where 
they try at least to supply their own food self-sufficiently. Others have be-
come homeless, together with new rural migrants and illegal foreign immi-
grants. Homelessness is most widespread in precisely the most dynamic cit-
ies because job opportunities are the most likely there. In contrast to the 
marginalised groups of Western European cities, some of the Central Euro-
pean homeless belong to the lower-middle class who have lost their homes 
for some reason, such as divorce, have been unable to find a new place to live, 
and have quickly become unemployed. The marginalisation of this group 
can hardly be reversed. 
Social polarisation has also been reflected in growing spatial segregation. 
The seclusion of the elite is most visible in the most sought-after residential 
districts. There are several reasons that can make an area attractive, such as 
a pleasant natural environment, the vicinity of the most important centres of 
urban life and cultural events in renovated downtown residential districts, or 
simply the neighbourhood of other members of the elite. The appearance of 
urban poverty is less conspicuous in the cities, but members of the lower class 
may be found almost everywhere, with the exception of the most expensive 
residential quarters. They live in larger or smaller concentrations in housing 
estates, in dilapidated tenements of old residential districts, and in old prole-
tarian quarters as well as inner city areas. Due to restricted mobility in re-
cent decades, demographic separation is very strong. Pensioners are charac-
teristically concentrated in old residential districts of the downtown. 
Transformation of the Built Environment 
Although the built environment is relatively resistant to change and invest-
ments in the construction sector have dramatically fallen in the last seven 
years, developments in this area are often spectacular. This is particularly the 
 
36 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
case in cities where the business sector and the entrepreneurial class have be-
come much stronger. 
The transformation of the built environment has been determined by 
three functional changes: expansion of commercial areas, transformation of 
industrial zones, and the altered character of housing. The image of the city 
has also been shaped by a new and immature aesthetics, a peculiar blend of 
obtrusive American shopping centres, newly rediscovered Central European 
elegance, elements of a national style and the architectural insipidity of the 
state socialist period. Next to a shabby tenement-building on the point of 
collapse one may well find the glittering new premises of a bank; elsewhere 
the garishness of new shops on the ground floor of an old building strikingly 
contrasts with the dilapidated flats above. 
New bank headquarters and office blocks bear spectacular witness to the 
expansion of the commercial sector. International finance houses and large 
foreign companies were the first to generate the kind of demand that could 
not be met by available buildings. Buildings housing new business services 
have also been primarily constructed by international investors, who have 
tended to rely on the less refined and schematic solutions of postmodern ar-
chitecture. The first buildings were erected near or actually in the historical 
centres of cities. In view of adverse traffic conditions, however, more remote 
subsidiary business centres have started to appear in locations that can be eas-
ily accessed by cars. Central commercial areas have expanded everywhere, 
mostly at the expense of downtown residential districts and the prestigious 
status of historical centres has invariably been exploited. Half of the area 
occupied by offices in Prague is to be found in the mediaeval centre (busi-
ness having quickly driven out residential functions). By contrast, one could 
scarcely identify a central business district in Warsaw, where there are also 
many vacant plots well-suited for further development. 
The built environment is also enhanced by newly-built, high quality resi-
dential buildings. These have been scattered throughout urban areas on vacant 
plots in prestigious residential districts. The launching of the rehabilitation of 
downtown quarters has been accompanied by gentrification and the pace of 
suburbanisation has also quickened. On the other hand, the construction of 
housing estates has been stopped. Since the population of most cities was rap-
  37 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
idly growing in the 1960s and 1970s, many people now live in housing es-
tates. The renovation and social rehabilitation of these is one of the unenviable 
tasks of the coming decades. 
Many old industrial areas have been left vacant due to the rapid decline 
and privatisation of state industry. This is particularly true in Hungary 
where the state has not saved uncompetitive companies from bankruptcy. The 
rehabilitation of old industrial areas has posed an interesting task for urban 
planning, although the lack of capital has not allowed for large-scale devel-
opments. The majority of former industrial buildings serve today as ware-
houses or house small industrial enterprises and discount stores. The first 
two large shopping centres of Central Europe have recently opened to the 
public in industrial areas of Budapest. One of these was built in the place of a 
dismantled factory, the other used buildings of a former barracks of the So-
viet army. 
International Relations and Participation in the 
International Competition of Cities 

The transition has put an end to the isolation of state socialism that severed 
the development of national settlement systems from one another. The open-
ing up of borders has made the direct penetration of global economic trends 
possible, a change that has also altered the conditions for the domestic com-
petition of cities. 
The changing function of borders has also altered the hierarchy of cities. 
Cities in border regions were condemned to stagnation for decades, but some 
of these have been developing dynamically since 1990 (especially in regions 
bordering on countries of the European Union). Small and medium-sized 
companies have been particularly successful here, proximity of borders hav-
ing rarely attracted the location of large-scale investments. 
It is highly significant that large cities have now joined the international 
competition of cities. Up to now this competition has had few Central Euro-
pean participants, because only a few cities had a sufficiently competitive 
local economy and infrastructure. Those cities that did, however, have be-
come the chief conduits of global trends. While they concentrate innovation 
 
38 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
arriving from developed countries in their respective areas, only inade-
quately do they transmit them further to their local urban network. In the 
first instance, competition drives them to establish connections with other 
European cities. This new competitiveness has been limited to Europe, since 
no Central European city can be said to play a global role, and in fact little 
attention has been given to the competitiveness of Central European cities. 
Nonetheless, the main conclusions to be drawn from a study by Conti 
(1994)
 are the following: 
1) only Budapest, Prague and Warsaw stand a good chance in the context 
of European competition; 
2) Budapest possessed certain advantages in comparison to the other two 
cities at the beginning of the 1990s; 
3) the principal characteristics of the three cities can be compared to 
those of the second division of Western European metropolises, espe-
cially cities located in Mediterranean coastal areas and Alpine regions 
(e.g. Lyon, Turin). 
The European integration of the largest cities has increased discrepancies 
within national urban systems. Many small and medium-sized industrial 
towns have long grappled with the transformational crisis, their main ambi-
tion being the attraction of industry withdrawing from Western Europe. The 
development of high standard business services and the transition to an in-
formational city will remain the privilege of a few, internationally competi-
tive metropolises in the near future. 
Conclusion 
In the light of what has gone before, I will now try to answer the two ques-
tions raised in the Introduction. The following is to be noted with regard to 
the main characteristics of the transition. The Central European urban sys-
tem has been shaped by three types of transformation. First, the transition 
from a state-planned economy and the political system of state socialism to 
a market economy and a democratic political system; second, a delayed 
transition from the industrial city to the postindustrial city; and finally, the 
  39 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
general transformation of the global economy. Another general trait of the 
transition is characterised by a peculiar mixture of spectacular novelties and 
uninterrupted continuity. Although the transformation of cities is generally a 
gradual process, the last fifty years have brought about dramatic changes in 
the composition and functioning of urban society and urban functions, as also 
in the built environment, first during the period of state socialism and then 
during the seven years of political and economic transition. At first sight, it 
may seem that there was a complete change after 1948 and 1990. Yet a 
marked continuity can be discovered beneath the surface. This continuity 
has been maintained by the slowly changing values and behaviour of the ur-
ban population, on the one hand, and the stasis in the built environment, on 
the other. This should also explain why European tendencies of urban de-
velopment can still be seen to have been at work in socialist urbanisation in 
Central Europe, even if in a somewhat modified form. By the same token, 
egalitarian values of state socialism are nowadays reflected in the uneasi-
ness about growing social inequalities and the fervent defence of the welfare 
state. 
The urban characteristics of the transition can be summarised as follows. 
• Reshuffling of the urban hierarchy. Differences within the urban sys-
tem have grown. Some cities, traditional industrial centres in particular, 
have been relegated to lower positions in the urban hierarchy. This 
relegation entails a high unemployment rate, growing urban poverty, 
decay of services and disintegration of the city’s cultural environment. 
New dynamic centres owe their success to the adaptability of the local 
population, and in some cases to a favourable geographical location as 
well. Social discrepancies in urban conditions and the availability of 
urban resources are not necessarily of recent date, but previously the 
consequences of these were counterbalanced by state paternalism. The 
same discrepancies, however, have been very strongly foregrounded by 
the sudden appearance of market competition. Changing markets and 
structural transformation account for the altered attitude to traditional 
urban values. Alterations in urban hierarchy could also be observed in 
traditional market economies in the 1970s. 
 
40 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
A small number of cities have acquired international functions due 
to the opening up of borders. Capitals of Central European countries in 
particular have been able to enter the European competition of cities 
and act as gateways mediating innovation from the West towards their 
respective national areas, and in some cases towards Eastern and South-
eastern Europe as well. However, this has intensified inequalities within 
the urban network. 
•  Transformation of urban society. An economic elite has appeared, in 
part recruited from the members of the political and cultural elite of 
state socialism. The immoderate consumption of this class may be 
shocking, but their accumulated wealth is seldom significant. To date, 
no Rockefeller dynasty has emerged in Central Europe (and in particu-
lar no phenomenon like the Rockefeller grandchildren, spending lav-
ishly on culture and charity from the inherited riches). Central Euro-
pean cities are characterised by underdeveloped middle classes, a gen-
eral absence of the ‘bourgeoisie’. This is not only a legacy of state so-
cialism since with the single exception of the Czech Republic, the mid-
dle classes have traditionally been weak in all Central European coun-
tries. It takes a long time before these middle classes gather strength and 
middle-class values strike root. This will also depend on how perma-
nent economic recovery will prove to be. Nevertheless, the great num-
ber of private enterprises that now exist may provide the basis for the 
strengthening of the new middle class. 
The massive proportions and new forms of urban poverty, such as 
permanent unemployment and homelessness, have provoked dismay 
and outrage. The Central European lower class is to a large extent still 
attached to its rural background. Many are unqualified migrants from 
rural areas who have been attracted to large cities by large state indus-
try, but could never become part of urban society. They lived in cheap 
flats, workers’ hostels or lodgings and maintained their links, which 
sometimes also meant part-time jobs, to their rural background. They 
have been the hardest hit by the dramatic decrease in industrial em-
ployment. Many have migrated back to their villages, hoping to be-
  41 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
come self-sufficient. However, since rural crisis has been even deeper 
than that in cities, they and other rural groups have soon returned to the 
cities to join the black economy. The insufficiency of their income for 
city rents, however, does not allow them to settle permanently in cities. 
The appearance of foreign immigrants represents a new develop-
ment in large cities. The multiethnic city has had a long tradition in the 
Austro-Hungarian Monarchy, but the various ethnic groups were al-
ways citizens of the Monarchy as well. After half a century of isola-
tion, immigrants from the Balkans, Eastern Europe and Asia have 
caught the population unprepared. Postcommunist countries, them-
selves looking back on a history of emigration, are as yet unable to 
form a clear immigration policy. 
• Changing factors of urban development. Under state socialism, urban 
development depended on the redistribution of the central budget, but 
now it is shaped by several factors. It is possible to distinguish between 
the  main agents and main co-ordinators of urban development. The 
principal agent of urban development is certainly the economy. Em-
ployment, investment and relations to other settlements are all the results 
of economic decisions, ranging from the location of the investment of 
transnational companies to the personal strategies of self-employed en-
trepreneurs. The local economy is responsible for the competitiveness, 
and therefore the success or failure of a given settlement. The presence 
of transnational companies has directly connected certain settlements 
to global trends. In terms of their influence on urban development, pri-
vate households are the next most important factor. The savings of the 
local population may significantly contribute to the development of lo-
cal infrastructure and most new homes are built by private households. 
The future of a settlement is largely dependent on the strategies of 
families (Will they move to other settlements? Will they educate their 
children locally? etc.). 
The decisions of these principal agents of the transformational proc-
ess are not motivated by objectives of urban development. They simply 
seek profit or personal welfare. The main co-ordinators of urban de-
velopment include local governments and, in some cases, civil organi-
 
42 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
sations. Local governments aim to use financial resources, economic 
decisions and public services to the advantage of the general develop-
ment of their settlement. The Central European system of local gov-
ernment is characterised by the following attributes: 
1) the great number and regional fragmentation of local governments; 
2) the absence or weakness of regional governments; 
3) the considerable independence of decision-making of local gov-
ernments coupled with strong financial dependence on the central 
budget. 
• Transformation of the built environment of cities. The renovation of in-
ner districts and the expansion of central business areas have been 
spectacular in all Central European countries. Although large-scale 
construction works of state socialism had usually not been located in 
downtown areas (politically motivated, demonstrative architectural un-
dertakings characteristic of Eastern European countries were a com-
parative rarity in Central Europe), many housing estates were built. 
The construction industry has, of course, also been hit by the economic 
recession of the transition period, but fresh demand has been generated 
by the new institutions of the emerging market economy (banks, of-
fices, shopping centres) as also by a well-to-do segment of the popula-
tion that can now afford better housing. This has led to the renovation 
of inner districts and accelerated suburbanisation. The rapid decline of 
housing estates into slums represents the ‘time bomb’ of urban devel-
opment, a possible source of a grave urban crisis of the future. 
In conclusion, I see no obstacles to the integration of Central Europe into 
the European urban system. Central Europe has never been completely iso-
lated from European urbanisation processes during the period of state so-
cialism. In addition, the state socialist ‘detour’ lasted only a little longer than 
forty years. The countries concerned all border on western market econo-
mies and European Union member countries. The existence of a common 
geographical space may well contribute to the evolution of multifaceted re-
gional connections. It is also advantageous that the European core region of 
urbanisation has begun to expand eastwards in the wake of German reunifi-
  43 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
cation and the economic progress of the Mediterranean–Alpine region. Inte-
gration has already been taking place on the periphery of the European ur-
ban system. Typical characteristics of the Central European subsystem in 
the near future may be the strong presence of industry, the concentration of 
business centres of international significance in a handful of cities, the 
weakness of the urban middle class, growing rural poverty and slow recov-
ery of the underdeveloped infrastructure. Integration will expose Central 
European cities to strong external competition. This competition may over-
whelm them; on the other hand, it may accelerate a long delayed process of 
modernisation. 
Notes 
1 This comprises Germany and Austria. 
2 This large demand is to be attributed to low technological standards, cost-
insensitive production and the politically privileged status of industry as 
well as the effective lobbying of industrial management. 
3 Budgetary resources that could have been spent on infrastructural develop-
ments were used to subsidise a chronically unproductive economy.  
4 Choice is always limited, for example, by the actual location of department 
stores or that of the nearest optician. This is true of all economic systems, 
but in the state-planned economy the location of the commercial sector did 
not correspond to consumer demand. On the contrary, it was determined 
by various priorities of planning and often followed the existing hierarchy 
in administration or public services. 
5 In Czechoslovakia and Poland, central planning directives governed the e-
conomy. These were issued by planning offices, sectoral ministries and 
trusts controlling industrial groups. Sectoral planning was abolished in 
Hungary in 1968. In principle, companies could make their decisions inde-
pendently. An overregulated, stimulated market and the strong dependence 
of the management of state-owned companies on governmental authorities 
appointing company managers rendered this independence illusory.  
6 The Czech form of privatisation, the so-called coupon-privatisation, has al-
lowed all citizens to participate in privatisation. Majority ownership of for-
merly state-owned companies has been acquired by small shareholders. 
The portfolios, however, are managed by investments funds. These are in 
 
44 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
turn in majority ownership of state banks. Despite a formal privatisation, 
therefore, the conservative government has maintained the possibility of 
state control in the economy. It has also made use of this possibility by 
keeping unemployment low through overemployment in these companies, 
and by controlling inflation through the central regulation of wages. It 
seems likely that the ‘moment of truth’ will soon arrive in the Czech Re-
public and the costs of transformation will also have to be paid by the 
Czech economy and society as well. It is not impossible, however, that 
these costs will be lower than in Poland and Hungary in 1990. 
7 The majority of postcommunist Central European countries belonged to the 
Monarchy. 
8 The share of tenements in housing was higher in large cities: 54% in Buda-
pest, 59% in Prague and 45% in Warsaw. 
9 For example, floorspace per capita, rooms per capita, number of homes per 
1000 inhabitants, share of rents in average income. 
10 Among all postcommunist countries, the share of flats returned to the ori-
ginal owner before the nationalisation was the highest in the Baltic states 
(7% of all homes in 1990). 
References 
Andrusz, G. – Harloe, M. – Szelényi, I. eds. (1996). Cities after Socialism. 
Oxford: Blackwell. 
Bennett, R. J. ed. (1993). Local Government in the New Europe. London: 
Belhaven. 
Braun, G. O. ed. (1994). Managing and Marketing Urban Development and 
Urban Life. Berlin: Dietrich Verlag. 
Brunet, R. ed. (1989). Les villes européennes. Paris: La Documentation 
Française. 
Cattan, N. – Pumain, D. – St. Julien, T. (1994). Le système des villes euro-
péennes. Paris: Economica. 
Conti, S. (1994). La città e la transizione post-socialista in Europa Centro-
Orientale. Torino: DIT Working Papers. No. 1. 
Dunford, M. – Kafkalas, G. eds. (1993). Cities and Regions in the New Eu-
rope. London: Belhaven. 
  45 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
Enyedi, Gy. (1992). ”Urbanisation in East Central Europe: Social Processes 
and Societal Responses in the State Socialist System.” Urban Studies 29. 
pp. 869–880. 
Enyedi, Gy. (1995). ”The Transition of Post-socialist Cities”. European Re-
view 3, No. 2. pp. 171–182. 
Enyedi, Gy. (1996). Urbanization under Socialism. In: Andrusz, G. – Har-
loe, M. – Szelényi, I. eds.: Cities after Socialism. Oxford: Blackwell. pp. 
100–119. 
Enyedi, Gy. (1997). Budapest: Return to European Competition. In: Jensen 
Butler, Ch. – Shachar, A. – van Weesep, J. eds.: European Cities in Com-
petition.
 Aldershot: Avebury. pp. 230–249. 
Enyedi, Gy. – Szirmai, V. (1992). Budapest – A Central European Capital. 
London: Belhaven. 
French, R. A. – Hamilton, F. E. I. eds. (1979). The Socialist City. New York: 
Wiley. 
Frydman, R. – Rapaczynski, A. (1994). Privatization in Eastern Europe: Is 
the State Withering Away? Budapest–London–New York: CEU Press. 
Godelier, M. (1987). ”The Analysis of Transition Processes”. International 
Social Science Journal 39, No. 4(114). pp. 447–459. 
Hall, P. (1993). ”Forces Shaping Urban Europe”. Urban Studies 30, No. 6. 
pp. 883–898. 
Ladányi, J. (1989). ”Changing Pattern of Residential Segregation in Buda-
pest”.  International Journal of Urban and Regional Research  13.  pp. 
555–572. 
Lever, W. F. (1993). ”Competition within the European Urban System”. Ur-
ban Studies 30, No. 6. pp. 935–948. 
Musil, J. (1993). ”Changing Urban Systems in Post-communist Societies in 
Central Europe: Analysis and Prediction”. Urban Studies 30, No. 6. pp. 
899–905. 
Pichler-Milanovich, N. (1994). ”The Role of Housing Policy in the Trans-
formation Process in Central-East European Cities”. Urban Studies 31
pp. 1097–1115. 
 
46 

Enyedi, György : Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities. 
Pécs : Centre for Regional Studies, 1998. 47. p. Discussion Papers, No. 21. 
 
Stark, D. (1992). ”Path Dependence and Privatization Strategies in East 
Central Europe”. East European Politics and Societies 6, No. 1. pp. 17–54. 
Szelényi, I. (1983). Urban Inequalities under State Socialism. Oxford: Ox-
ford University Press. 
Turner, B. – Hegedüs, J. – Tosics, I. (1992). The Reform of Housing in East-
ern Europe and the Soviet Union. London: Routledge. 
Węcławowicz, G. (1992). The Socio-spatial Structure of the Socialist Cities 
in East-Central Europe: The Case of Poland, Czechoslovakia and Hun-
gary. In: Lando, F. (ed.) Urban and Rural Geography. Venice: Cafosca-
rina. pp. 129–140. 
 
 
  47 




Discussion Papers 1998. No. 21. 
Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities
 
The Discussion Papers series of the Centre for Regional Studies of the Hungari-
an Academy of Sciences was launched in 1986 to publish summaries of re-
search findings on regional and urban development. 
The series has 3 or 4 issues a year. It will be of interest to geographers, econo-
mists, sociologists, experts of law and political sciences, historians and every-
body else who is, in one way or another, engaged in the research of spatial as-
pects of socio-economic development and planning. 
The series is published by the Centre for Regional Studies. 
Individual copies are available on request at the Centre. 
 
Postal address 
Centre for Regional Studies of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences 
P.O. Box 199, 7601 PÉCS, HUNGARY 
Phone: (36–72) 212–755, 233–704 
Fax: (36–72) 233–704 
 
 
Director general 
Gyula HORVÁTH 
Editor 
László HRUBI 
 
* * * 
Forthcoming in the Discussion Papers series 
Changes in the Politico-geographical Position of 
Hungary in the 20th Century 
by 
 

Discussion Papers 1998. No. 21. 
Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities
 
Zoltán, HAJDÚ
 

Discussion Papers 1998. No. 21. 
Transformation in Central European Postsocialist Cities
 
Papers published in the Discussion Papers series 
No. 1  OROSZ, Éva (1986): Critical Issues in the Development of Hungarian Public 
Health with Special Regard to Spatial Differences 
No. 2  ENYEDI, György – ZENTAI, Viola (1986): Environmental Policy in Hun-
gary 
No. 3  HAJDÚ, Zoltán (1987): Administrative Division and Administrative Geo-
graphy in Hungary 
No. 4  SIKOS T., Tamás (1987): Investigations of Social Infrastructure in Rural Set-
tlements of Borsod County 
No. 5  HORVÁTH, Gyula (1987): Development of the Regional Management of the 
Economy in East-Central Europe 
No. 6  PÁLNÉ KOVÁCS, Ilona (1988): Chance of Local Independence in Hungary 
No. 7  FARAGÓ, László – HRUBI, László (1988): Development Possibilities of 
Backward Areas in Hungary 
No. 8  SZÖRÉNYINÉ KUKORELLI, Irén (1990): Role of the Accessibility in De-
velopment and Functioning of Settlements 
No. 9  ENYEDI, György (1990): New Basis for Regional and Urban Policies in East-
Central Europe 
No. 10  RECHNITZER, János (1990): Regional Spread of Computer Technology in 
Hungary 
No. 11  SIKOS T., Tamás (1992): Types of Social Infrastructure in Hungary (to be not 
published
No. 12  HORVÁTH, Gyula – HRUBI, László (1992): Restructuring and Regional 
Policy in Hungary 
No. 13  ERDŐSI, Ferenc (1992): Transportation Effects on Spatial Structure of Hun-
gary 
No. 14  PÁLNÉ KOVÁCS, Ilona (1992): The Basic Political and Structural Problems 
in the Workings of Local Governments in Hungary 
No. 15  PFEIL, Edit (1992): Local Governments and System Change. The Case of a 
Regional Centre 
No. 16  HORVÁTH, Gyula (1992): Culture and Urban Development (The Case of 
Pécs) 
No. 17  HAJDÚ, Zoltán (1993): Settlement Network Development Policy in Hungary 
in the Period of State Socialism (1949–1985) 
No. 18  KOVÁCS, Teréz (1993): Borderland Situation as It Is Seen by a Sociologist 
No. 19  HRUBI, L. – KRAFTNÉ SOMOGYI, Gabriella (eds.)(1994): Small and me-
dium-sized firms and the role of private industry in Hungary 
No. 20  BENKŐNÉ LODNER, Dorottya (1995): The Legal-Administrative Ques-
tions of Environmental Protection in the Republic of Hungary